1 / 21

Taxes and markets. Most of the discussion will focus on: Excise taxes: taxes on specific goods, like gasoline, cigarette

Taxes and markets. Most of the discussion will focus on: Excise taxes: taxes on specific goods, like gasoline, cigarettes, and alcoholic beverages. When the government levies a tax on a good, who bears the burden of taxation (buyers or sellers)?

benjamin
Télécharger la présentation

Taxes and markets. Most of the discussion will focus on: Excise taxes: taxes on specific goods, like gasoline, cigarette

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Taxes and markets. Most of the discussion will focus on: Excise taxes: taxes on specific goods, like gasoline, cigarettes, and alcoholic beverages. When the government levies a tax on a good, who bears the burden of taxation (buyers or sellers)? This is a question about tax incidence (the study of who bears the burden of taxation).

  2. We will see that: The one who “pays” the tax (the one who is required to give payment to the government) . . . . . . is not necessarily the one who “pays” the tax (the one who bears the burden of taxation). Usually, it’s the seller who is required to give payment to the government. But we will consider the other case as well: buyer gives payment to government.

  3. Let’s suppose the government levies a $0.50/unit tax on the market for widgets . . . . . . and buyers are required to send payment to the government. (For every widget you buy, you have to send a check for $0.50 to the government.) In supply and demand graphs, let’s interpret “price” (plotted on vertical axis) as the amount, per unit sold, that changes hands between buyer and seller. How will tax affect supply and demand graph?

  4. ($/widget) Demand curve D1 to start. p1 p1 - 0.50 D1 D2 widgets/day Q1 When tax goes into effect, demand will shift down by $0.50/unit. Consider one particular point on D1 Before tax, when buyers have to give p1 $/widget, they demand Q1 widgets/day. Same will be true after tax goes into effect. But (!) -- after tax is in effect, if buyers are to give up p1 $/widget in total, amount paid to seller must be p1 - 0.50 $/widget. Original point shifts down by 0.50 $/widget. Same story for each point on D1 -- demand shifts down by 0.50.

  5. Now let’s look at a $0.50/unit tax on widgets . . . . . . with sellers required to send payment to the government. (For every widget a seller sells, she has to send a check to the government for $0.50.) Remember, “price” plotted on vertical axis is the amount, per unit, that changes hands between buyer and seller.

  6. Supply curve S1 to start. ($/widget) S2 S1 p1 + 0.50 p1 widgets/day Q1 When tax goes into effect, supply will shift up by $0.50/unit. Consider one particular point on S1 Before tax, when sellers “pocket” p1 $/widget, they supply Q1 widgets/day. Same will be true after tax goes into effect. But (!) -- after tax is in effect, if sellers are to “pocket” p1 $/widget, amount received from buyer must be p1 + 0.50 $/widget. Original point shifts up by 0.50 $/widget. Same story for each point on S1 -- supply shifts up by 0.50

  7. Recap: If the buyers are required to send tax payment to government: Demand shifts down by amount of tax. (Demand decreases.) If sellers are required to send tax payment to government: Supply shifts up by amount of tax. (Supply decreases -- even though it’s an upward shift.) What about the effects on market equilibrium?

  8. ($/widget) To start: D1, S1, p1*, Q1* t $/widget S1 pb* p1* . . . shifting demand down by t $/widget. ps* D1 D2 Q2* Q1* (widgets/day) Equilibrium quantity goes down: Q1* to Q2* New “equilibrium price” is a sellers’ price: ps* Consider a t $/unit tax on widgets -- and buyers are required to send payment to government. Then the tax goes into effect . . . Buyers’ price is t $/widget higher: pb* = ps* + t

  9. To start: Same D1, S1, p1*, Q1* as before. ($/widget) S2 t $/widget S1 pb* p1* . . . shifting supply up by t $/widget. ps* D1 Q2* Q1* (widgets/day) Equilibrium quantity goes down: Q1* to Q2* New “equilibrium price” is a buyers’ price: pb* Sellers’ price is t $/widget lower: ps* = pb* - t Consider same t $/widget tax -- but this time, sellers are required to send payment to government. Then the tax goes into effect . . .

  10. ($/widget) ($/widget) S2 S1 S1 pb* pb* p1* p1* ps* ps* D1 D1 D2 Q2* Q1* (widgets/day) Q2* Q1* (widgets/day) What difference does it make if buyers “pay” the tax, or sellers “pay” the tax? No difference! Let’s bring in the graph from the “buyers ‘pay’” analysis. Now let’s overlay the graph for the “sellers ‘pay’” case.

  11. The effects of an excise tax are independent of whether buyers or sellers are required to send the tax payment to the government. With no tax, “buyers’ price” (the amount buyers pay out, per unit) is the same as “sellers’ price” (the amount sellers “pocket,” per unit). The fundamental effect of a tax is to introduce a gap, or “tax wedge” between the buyers’ and sellers’ prices. This observation gives us another way to do the analysis.

  12. ($/widget) tax wedge S1 pb* p1* ps* D1 Q2* Q1* (widgets/day) Let’s go back to the original (before-tax-is-introduced) demand and supply curves again. The tax introduces a tax wedge of t $/widget between buyers’ and sellers’ prices. Take a vertical bar of height t $/widget and see where it “fits” between supply and demand to the left of equil. This determines pb*, ps*, Q2*.

  13. Again, the effects of the tax are independent of who “pays the tax” (sends the check to the government). But what are the effects? From the graph, we see: Equilibrium quantity falls (from Q1* to Q2*). The price buyers pay increases (from p1* to pb*). The price sellers “pocket” decreases (from p1* to ps*).

  14. Notice: In general, the burden of the tax is “shared” between buyers and sellers . . . . . . buyers’ price goes up some, . . . and sellers’ price goes down some. Often we hear: “When an excise tax is levied on a good, sellers will ‘pass the tax along’ to buyers.”

  15. ($/widget) At a buyers’ price of p1* + t, quantity demanded is Q3 . . . S1 p1* + t p1* D1 Q3 Q1* (widgets/day) Excess supply -- price must fall . . . What if they tried to “pass the tax along” (mark up the original price by full amount of tax)? . . . and sellers’ price would be p1* so quantity supplied is Q1*. . . . to the level of pb* from previous graphs.

  16. We’ve seen that the effects of a tax are independent of who “pays” the tax ( . . . independent of who is required to give payment to government). But this basic lesson isn’t understood by everyone! FICA (Federal Insurance Contribution Act) payroll taxes. -- pays for Social Security and Medicare. -- takes about 15.3% of (before-tax) earnings for typical worker (in 2008). -- Congress mandated a 50-50 division. (More on FICA: http://www.ssa.gov/ . . .) But the “mandated division” is irrelevant!

  17. But then, what does determine how the burden of a tax is distributed? (Now coming back to the tax incidence question.) In the graphs we’ve drawn, it looks like an approximately 50-50 split: -- buyers’ price goes up by about half of the tax. -- sellers’ price goes down by the other half. Does it always work out this way?

  18. Tax incidence and elasticity ($/widget) tax wedge pb* Supply p1* ps* Demand (widgets/day) Suppose that supply is more elastic than demand: For a given “tax wedge” . . . . . . buyers’ price rises more than sellers’ price falls. Tax incidence falls more heavily on buyers (the ones with the less elastic price-quantity relation).

  19. Now suppose that demand is more elastic than supply. With the same initial equilibrium price as before . . . ($/widget) Supply tax wedge pb* p1* Demand ps* (widgets/day) . . . and the same “tax wedge” as before . . . . . . sellers’ price falls more than buyers’ price rises. Tax incidence falls more heavily on sellers (the ones with the less elastic price-quantity relation).

  20. Cigarettes are subject to significant (state and federal) excise taxes. The demand for cigarettes is relatively inelastic. (One study by Craig Gallet and John List in Health Economics, 2003, reports that own price elasticity estimates average -0.40.) (http://www3.interscience.wiley.com/ . . . ) Elasticity of supply? -- most likely higher than 0.40. So the incidence of cigarette excise taxes falls more heavily on buyers than sellers.

  21. Cigarette excise tax rates. Federal: $0.39/pack Iowa: $1.36/pack. The five highest: NY ($2.75/pack), NJ (2.58), MA (2.51), RI (2.46), WA (2.02) The six lowest: SC ($0.07/pack), MO (0.17), MS (0.18), KY-VA (0.30) (http://tobaccofreekids.org/research/factsheets/pdf/0097.pdf)

More Related