1 / 42

Scott Wentland wentlandsa@longwood.edu 434-395-2160 Longwood University 201 High Street Farmville, VA 23901

Scott Wentland wentlandsa@longwood.edu 434-395-2160 Longwood University 201 High Street Farmville, VA 23901. What Determines Value?. Part 1 – The Labor Theory of Value and the Diamonds/Water Paradox. Why are some things more valuable than others?

cora
Télécharger la présentation

Scott Wentland wentlandsa@longwood.edu 434-395-2160 Longwood University 201 High Street Farmville, VA 23901

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Scott Wentland wentlandsa@longwood.edu 434-395-2160 Longwood University201 High StreetFarmville, VA 23901

  2. What Determines Value? Part 1 – The Labor Theory of Value and the Diamonds/Water Paradox

  3. Why are some things more valuable than others? • How can “thinking on the margin” and cost-benefit analysis help us understand value?

  4. That’s easy. The stuff we needthe most is the most valuable. • Houses are expensive • Gas is expensive • Medicine can be very expensive • Is something really more valuable because we need it more?

  5. Adam Smith wrote about this in 1776 • The Wealth of Nations (1776) • Smith was the father of economics and The Wealth of Nations is one of economics most important books (more about Smith later…) • Water/Diamonds Paradox • Why are diamonds more valuable than water?

  6. Water is essential to human life • Other than air, there is literally nothing more important to our survival as water • Humansneed water • But, water is cheap

  7. Diamonds are not essential to human life • They are shiny stones, used in jewelry and a few other uses (like cutting) • Diamonds = bling  we don’t need bling. • But, diamonds are expensive!

  8. If value doesn’t necessarily come from need, then where does it come from? • Adam Smith’s answer: how much work goes into it • “The real price of every thing, what every thing really costs to the man who wants to acquire it, is the toil and trouble of acquiring it.” • Labor theory of value

  9. Water is easy come by, in most places • In the old days, pump water from a well • Now, it comes out of the faucet • Diamonds are hard to make • Need to be mined from a far-away land • Need to be precisely cut and polished • If a diamond maker goes to the trouble of making the diamond, he/she will want something back in return • Something of at least equal value

  10. Diamonds are more valuable because it takes more labor to make a diamond? • This story is incomplete. Why? • Does more labor always mean more value?

  11. Grandma spent a lot of time knitting this sweater…is it valuable?

  12. Countless, highly skilled people helped make these movies… • Are these movies valuable to studios?

  13. What have we learned? • The labor theory of value is obviously incomplete. • Does not account for other costs • Does not account for demand • Not necessarily ‘thinking on the margin’ • Next part: Is there a better way to resolve this diamonds/water paradox?

  14. What Determines Value? Part 2 – Marginal Analysis and Resolving the Diamonds/Water Paradox

  15. Where does value really come from? • Individuals(the rest of this lecture) • First look at how individuals determine value for themselves • Individuals think “on the margin” • Markets(next lecture) • Markets are made up of individuals (consumers and producers) who trade with one another • Markets can be best understood by understanding the laws of supply and demand

  16. Individuals have value for consuming something, independent of what the price actually is • Consumption (or use) value is subjective • Price of a can of Coca-Cola = $1 • I may buy it, because it is worth more than $1 to me • I might be willing to pay $2 or $3. • You may not buy it, because it is not worth $1 to you • You might be willing to pay $0.50 • This value may vary from person to person

  17. Does this mean you wouldn’t want a Coke if you could buy it for, say, $0.75? • Exchangevalue is not subjective • You may buy the Coke for $0.75 and try to sell it for $1.00 • People trade/exchange/buy/sell because they either want to 1) consume it or 2) re-sell it 1) depends on your own value for it 2) depends on the market value for it

  18. Individuals think (and make a lot of decisions, like consumption decisions) on the margin • In economics, “the margin” refers to the “next increment” of whatever you are deciding to do • Should I have one more drink? • I was happy with the first cup of coffee, should I have a second cup? A third? A forth? • Should I study an additional hour? • Should I take one more class this semester?

  19. Example: • Suppose you are studying for an exam at Starbucks • You plan to stay for several hours • You drink energy drinks to give you an extra kick of energy • Do you order all of your energy drinks all at once?

  20. You probably think on the margin: • Buy the first when you get there • Buy a second when you are getting a little tired • Buy a third when the second one wears off…

  21. Why do you buy the first energy drink? • Breaking it down: • Cost of one energy drink = $3.00 • Benefit of one energy drink > $3.00 • You would be willing to pay as much as $4.00 for this • You buy the energy drink because: Benefit > Cost (for the first drink)

  22. Why do you buy the first energy drink? • Marginal cost • The additional cost for one additional unit • $3.00 • Marginal benefit • The additional benefit for one additional unit • $4.00 for the second unit Marginal Benefit > Marginal Cost $4.00 > $3.00

  23. Individuals are always weighing costs and benefits • This is called cost-benefit analysis • This can be either intentional or unemotional/subconscious • Economics’ prediction about human behavior: If Marginal Benefit > Marginal Cost, DO IT!

  24. Why do you buy the second energy drink? • Breaking it down: • Marginal Cost of the second energy drink = $3.00 • Benefit of second energy drink > $3.00 • You would be willing to pay as much as $3.50 for this

  25. Why do you buy the second energy drink? • Marginal cost • The additional cost for one additional unit • $3.00 • Marginal benefit • The additional benefit for one additional unit • $3.50 for the second unit Marginal Benefit > Marginal Cost $3.50 > $3.00

  26. Why do you buy the third energy drink? • Marginal cost • The additional cost for one additional unit • $3.00 • Marginal benefit • The additional benefit for one additional unit • $3.05 for the second unit Marginal Benefit > Marginal Cost $3.05 > $3.00

  27. Why is my marginal benefit shrinking? • I’m not as satisfied with the 3rd as I was the 2nd or 1st… • I am less satisfied with “more of the same” • I may be getting tired of drinking energy drinks • It may not provide the same “kick” • This idea is linked to diminishing marginal utility • As I consume more and more of the same thing, the additional happiness (or marginal utility) diminishes with each additional unit

  28. At some point, you choose not to buy any more • Why? • Because the Marginal Cost > Marginal Benefit • Second prediction about human behavior: If Marginal Benefit < Marginal Cost, Then DON’T DO IT!

  29. Cost-Benefit Analysis Conclusions: Choose to do more of something if: MB > MC Choose NOT to do more of something if: MB < MC Happiest when we have reached: MB = MC • The third can was closest to this optimal point

  30. Diminishing marginal utility and “bulk pricing” • Vendors know the consumers have diminishing marginal utility, so they price accordingly: • One for $3, Two for $5 • The marginal cost of 1st = $3 • The marginal cost of 2nd= $2 • This is different than average cost • AC = Price / Quantity • Average cost = $5 / 2 = $2.50 • Marginal cost may not always be constant

  31. How does marginal analysis (or “thinking at the margin”) resolve our diamonds/water paradox? • Water is incredibly valuable to us, but not so muchat the margin • When we want to buy a bottle of water, we’re usually not completely dehydrated • An additional bottle of water might make us less thirsty, but is not usually a matter of life and death

  32. One more bottle of water usually means…I’m a bit less thirsty • How much is that worth to you? Maybe $1 or $2. • The question is not usually a “lifetime of water” vs. “no water”…it is usually choosing to buy water at the margin • One more diamond usually means…I am much, much happier (or my significant other is much happier!) • How much is that worth to you? Hundreds? Thousands?

  33. Each additional diamond is still worth a lot to you… • For consumption, who wouldn’t want more diamonds? • Each additional bottle of water…not so much. • Always? • Alone in the desert, you may be glad to trade a diamond for a bottle of water! • Most of the time, we’re not in a desert.

  34. When we think on the margin, we can see how an additional diamond > an additional bottle of water • Consumption value is subjective • Differs from person to person • Differs from unit to unit (additional units are usually valued less) • When we think on the margin, we make good, rational decisions (where MB > MC) • We are happiest when we come to MB = MC • This is sometimes called cost-benefit analysis or marginal analysis

  35. Marginal analysis or marginalism supplants the labor theory of value • Developed by 19th century economists after Smith, called the “marginal revolution” • Why is this important? • Karl Marx’s theories depended on the labor theory of value • Relatively simple concept devastates a key tenant of Marxist/Communist economic theory

  36. What if I don’t like diamonds? And my significant other doesn’t like diamonds? • If I found one (or could buy one for cheap), would I just throw it away (or not buy it)? • No, you can always sell it (or exchange it for something you do like) • Exchange value is not subjective • We can sell it on the market at some market price • Later: what determines that market price? How does the market value things?

  37. For additional information see: http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Paradox_of_value http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Marginalism http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Cost_benefit http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Marginal_concepts

More Related