1 / 50

“You can’t be happier than your wife” Divorce and the distribution of life satisfaction across spouses

“You can’t be happier than your wife” Divorce and the distribution of life satisfaction across spouses. Cahit Guven (Deakin University) and Claudia Senik (Paris School of Economics). September 4, 2009. What this paper does. Ask:

elina
Télécharger la présentation

“You can’t be happier than your wife” Divorce and the distribution of life satisfaction across spouses

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. “You can’t be happier than your wife”Divorce and the distribution of life satisfaction across spouses Cahit Guven (Deakin University) and Claudia Senik (Paris School of Economics) September 4, 2009

  2. What this paper does • Ask: • Does the distribution of life satisfaction across spouses matters per se? • Does it predict divorce? • (beyond the level of individual satisfaction of each spouse) • Try to answer this question using the GSOEP panel data 1983-2007 • 359958 observations, 45225 individuals, 13456 couples

  3. Motivation: 1. Economic consequences of divorce • Impact of actual and expected divorce on factors of GDP growth: • Fertility and number of children • Capital accumulation in marital specific assets (Becker, 1974) • Human capital of children (education, care, expenditure) • Houses • Specific human capital of spouses • Labor market force participation of women • Implications for public policy concerning family and women’s labor force participation • Generalize the evidence on aversion to inequality? • to “other contracts of indefinite duration where the parties involved have the option of termination, perhaps with a penalty” (Becker et al. 1977)

  4. Motivation: 2. aversion to inequality in households? • Literature on income distribution and subjective well-being • Negative association between income inequality and SWB • Literature on income comparisons and well-being • income comparisons and other types of comparisons inside the household (Clark, 2005) associated with lower levels of happiness • Literature on marriage and divorce • Essentially self-centered decision of getting/remaining married • But no literature on whether the distribution of subjective well-being inside the household matters.

  5. Motivation: 3. Reliability of subjective data • Show impact of subjective variables on actual choices, decisions and actions • Inequality in Subjective Well-Being Divorce

  6. The economics of marriage and divorce • Marriage is viewed as a means to maximize individual welfare and collective output (Becker, 1974, 1991) • Joint production, joint consumption (e.g. children) • Increasing returns, division of labor, risk pooling, coordination • Rational individuals: • look at her level of well-being inside marriage versus outside and decides whether to become/remain married or not (Becker) • Other compatible assumptions: • Altruism, intra-household externalities of welfare (Powthdawee, 2004)

  7. Unitary models of household • Basic unitary model: • One decision-maker • Consider only aggregate utility for all members • More sophisticated models (Becker 1974, 1991) • Head of household is altruistic: takes into account individual preferences of household members • Gains of marriage shared among members of family depending on marriage market (sex ratio) • Upfront payments in traditional societies: dowries or bride-price • Division of labor in modern families

  8. Unitary models of household (continued) • Income pooling • behavior of spouses (labor supply, expenditures) only depend on aggregate exogenous income • Does not depend on the distribution of income across members • But unitary model of household rejected by empirical tests • Phipps and Burton (1992)

  9. Collective models of the household • Cooperative models (following Chiappori, 1992): • 1) Sharing rule depends on individual preferences and individual bargaining power (distribution factors) • Bargaining power depends on outside wage, divorce legislation, child custody rules, remarriage market, etc. • 2) Each individual maximizes his utility under the budget constraint defined in first stage • Pareto efficiency of all decisions • Non cooperative models of Nash bargaining • not necessarily Pareto-efficient

  10. The economics of marriage and divorce • But are all equilibria in terms of distribution of welfare across spouses stable? • Beyond purely self-regarding motives, are there also concerns for the distribution of well-being?

  11. Concerns for the distribution of well-being across spouses? • We try to answer this question, controlling for the classical correlates of the value of marriage/ value of outside options (Weiss and Willis, 1997) • Income, education, age, of each spouse, children, etc. • We take life satisfaction as given, as the result of bargaining and all intra-household decisions and allocations (chores, etc.) • We find a positive statistical association between the difference in life satisfaction across spouses and the probability that they will divorce in later years.

  12. Possible mechanisms • Aversion to inequality in terms of happiness inside couples • The gap in satisfaction is a sign of the degrading quality of the marriage technology • altruism, sharing, spillovers of SWB, pooling • Impossibility to transfer well-being between spouses • Makes compensation of the less happy spouse impossible • Positive assortative mating in terms of life satisfaction more stable • Matching on the set-point of happiness (Lucas and Schimmack, 2006), Fujita and Diener (2005), Lucas et al. (2003)

  13. Other alternative explanations • Reverse causality: the perspective of divorce makes one spouse more unhappy and creates the happiness gap that we observe • Infidelity: One of the spouses is contemplating (or experiencing) forming another couple, and this creates the gap between him and his spouse •  We try to rule out these mechanisms using long distance lagged variables, pre-marital life satisfaction levels and other strategies.

  14. Some related papers on marriage and divorce using subjective happiness data • GSOEP: • Lucas et al. (2003), Stutzer and Frey (2006), Zimmermann and Easterlin (2006): Marriage makes people happy (beyond happier people getting married) • Lucas and Schimmack (2006): Similarity of happiness of spouses • BHPS: • Gardner and Oswald (2002): Marriage increases life expectancy • Gardner and Oswald (2005): Divorcing couples become happier • Powdhtavee (2009): Happiness spillover effect between spouses

  15. Data • GSOEP panel data 1983-2007 • Individual and partner identification variable for 45226 people and 252753 observations • Number of couples: 13456 • Number of divorces : 4074 • GSOEP includes a separate spell dataset for marital status. • Constructed dataset: sample of women with all socio-demographic variables pertaining to themselves and their husband. Before, during and after marriage. • Symmetrically: sample of men with all variables pertaining to themselves and their wife.

  16. Attrition • % 10 of couples in the sample for the whole period (23 years) • Average duration of a couple in the sample is 13.4 years • By men: 13.3 years, by women: 13.5 years • Characteristics of those who are more likely to leave the sample: men, non-German, young, unmarried, seperated (Kroh and Spieß, 2008) • We weight the observations by the inverse of the probability to remain in the sample.

  17. Estimates • We run a dprobit estimate of the probability to divorce • Divorce t+1 = f (total happinesst, absolute value of happiness difference between spousest; age t, age differencet, household incomet, number of childrent) (1) • Controls =classical determinants of marriage and divorce (Weiss and Willis, 1997) • Cluster standard errors at individual level

  18. Comparability of self-declared happiness of spouses? • Individual fixed effects or couple fixed effects controls for the anchoring effect • Interpretation: probability of divorce depending on the evolution of the gap in SWB • Impact of subjective representation of happiness rather than objective happiness

  19. Description of the data and main variables

  20. How happy are you? (scale: 0-10) Not weighted

  21. Absolute difference in happiness across spouses, 1984-2007

  22. Couples who marry and do not divorce throughout the sample (1984-2007)

  23. Total happiness, happiness gap around the year of divorce Married and partnering together

  24. Individual happiness and happiness gap around the year of divorce Married and partnering together

  25. Total happiness and happiness gap around the year of divorce Legally Married Only

  26. Total residual happiness, residual happiness gap around the year of divorce Married and partnering together Residuals of equation (1)

  27. % of divorces depending on happiness differences Married and partnering together Residuals of equation (1)

  28. OLS estimates of the % of people who divorce T-statistics are reported in absolute values. The second column is estimated only at the first year of marriages. Number of observations=number of years.

  29. ResultsProbability to divorce and absolute value of happiness difference One row per control show only wife results during the whole presentation put interesting coefficient in bold Standard errors clustered at individual level

  30. Happiness difference as a categorical variable Standard errors clustered at individual level

  31. Hapiness difference and marriage duration:Only for those who married in the sample • Do for those who marry in the sample Standard errors clustered at individual level

  32. Avoid the risk of reverse causation or infidelityHappiness gap in the first year of marriage predicts divorce Write Dprobit

  33. Lagged values of absolute happiness differences Write Dprobit Controls: total happiness, age, age difference, number of children, ln household income. Each coefficient corresponds to a separate regression.

  34. Robustness: additional controlsSample of wives Write Dprobit Controls as usual, cluster(individual)

  35. Robustness continued. Sample of wives Write Dprobit Split into several tables Controls: as usual. Cluster(individual).

  36. Robustness continued. Sample of wives Write Dprobit Split into several tables Controls: as usual. Cluster(individual). Column 5: omitted category: one spouse born in Germany and the other is not.

  37. Robustess continued. Sample of wives Write Dprobit Self-reported health : 5 is very good health; 1 bad health. Individual fixed effects is estimated using conditional logit.

  38. Write Dprobit Omitted: 1) different nationalities, 2) German origin and living inWest-Germany, 4) Each manages own money separately. Specification 3 is estimated by weighting with the inverse of the individual longitudinal staying probabilities which is provided in the GSOEP. In specification 5, importance of family:1 very unimportant; 4 is very important and, is treated as a continuous variable.

  39. Robustness Same results obtained on the sample of husbands Unexpected income shocks, such as disability and unemployment increase the absolute value of happiness difference but, can not predict divorce.

  40. Interpretation • Aversion for inequality of happiness • Positive assortative mating in terms of happiness • Indeed there are signs of assortative mating in the data

  41. Assortative mating by happiness level in the first year of marriage 1 if happiness<5 2 if happiness=5, 6, 7 3 if happiness>7

  42. Assortative mating by residual happinessin the first year of marriage 1 if residual happiness>0 0 if residual happiness<0

  43. Happiness gap between divorced people remains higher than between married people(although it decreases) Attention: need to take absdslife not dslife

  44. Conclusions • Some evidence suggestive that more equal distributions of subjective well-being are more favorable to marriage continuation. • Reflects bargaining inside household or assortative matching. • One additional motive of marriage/divorce beyond purely self-regarding motives. • Predictive power of SWB variables.

  45. Descriptive statistics of the main variables

  46. Descriptive statistics of the main variables

  47. Transition matrix of partnership The estimates excludes people who lose partners due to death. 2.02 is the probability of separation from partner conditional on having the same partner in the previous period. Ratios are in percentages.

  48. Correlation matrix of happiness variables Happiness difference =Happiness of husband – happiness of wife

  49. Transition matrix of marital status We do not differentiate between separations and divorces in the paper. Hence separation/divorce probability for marital relationships is 0.93+0.31=1.24. Ratios are in percentages.

  50. Correlation matrix of lagged absolute value of happiness differences

More Related