1 / 36

Taxes and Labour Supply Theory, Evidence and Policy David Phillips (IFS)

Taxes and Labour Supply Theory, Evidence and Policy David Phillips (IFS). Outline. The Basics: Income, Substitution and Deadweight Loss Enriching the Model: Fixed costs and more 3. Measurement Issues: Econometric Problems 4. A Review of the Emprical Evidence

flora
Télécharger la présentation

Taxes and Labour Supply Theory, Evidence and Policy David Phillips (IFS)

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Taxes and Labour Supply Theory, Evidence and Policy David Phillips (IFS)

  2. Outline • The Basics: Income, Substitution and Deadweight Loss • Enriching the Model: Fixed costs and more • 3. Measurement Issues: Econometric Problems • 4. A Review of the Emprical Evidence • Alternate Measures: Taxable Income Elasticities • Policies: Mini Jobs for Lone Parents • Conclusions

  3. The Basics • ‘Labour Supply’ is the supply of effort and time by individuals for monetary compensation. • Working out revenue implications of tax reforms • Working out the ‘optimal’ tax rate structure. • Theoretical and empirical work has traditionally focused upon hours of work but more recently a recognition of: • The participation decision (extensive margin) • Effort and Compensation Form • But what basic lessons can we use from Econ 101?

  4. Income and Substitution Effects NI Higher tax rate reduces net income. If leisure is a normal good this reduces demand for leisure and increases Labour Supply. Higher tax rate reduces the marginal wage and hence the price of an extra hour of leisure. This acts to decrease Labour supply. A A’ A’’ l H Tax has an ambiguous effect on Labour Supply

  5. Abolition of the 10p Starting Rate And Cutting Basic Rate to 20p NI Old Tax Schedule What about Labour Supply?? l H New Tax Schedule

  6. Abolition of the 10p Starting Rate And Cutting Basic Rate to 20p • Those not working or earning less than the personal allowance are unaffected. • Those previously paying starting rate have lower income (work more) but face a higher marginal rate (work less) – Ambiguous. • Those paying basic rate and earning upto about £19,000 have lower income (work more) and a lower marginal rate (work more) – Work MORE. • Those paying basic rate and earning more than £19,000 have higher income (work less) but face a lower marginal rate (work more) - Ambiguous

  7. Elasticity of Labour Supply • There are two types of elasticity we are interested in: • The uncompensated elasticity. • The compensated elasticity. • Linked together by the Slutsky Equation: • εh = εm - [(w*h)/(w*T+y)]* εi • εh = Compensated Elasticity w = Wage • εm= Uncompensated Elasticity h = hours of work • εi = Income Elasticity T = time endowment • y = Unearned Income

  8. Tax Rates and Tax Revenues The uncompensated elasticity determines revenue: Change in Revenue ≈ (1- εm)*(%Δ(1-t)w)*w*h*t NI Here a tax rise increases revenue but if labour supply is elastic would see a fall in revenue. A A’’ l H

  9. Tax Rates and Deadweight Loss When substitution occurs there is always deadweight loss. It is determined by the compensated elasticity.

  10. The Hours Distribution Now imagine a tax cut. The model predicts some not working will enter work and do 1 or 2 hours per week. But we don’t observe this... Why?

  11. Adding Fixed Costs of Work When you start work there are certain fixed costs: Transport costs Work clothing costs Childcare costs And others NI Fixed costs mean not working better than working few hours -provided leisure and income are both ‘goods’ A’ A l H

  12. The Welfare System: Non Convexity The welfare system (benefits and tax credits) mean that people on low incomes can face very high effective marginal tax rates. This ‘non convexity’ causes similar discontinuous labour supply responses. NI Introducing non-convexities (e.g. WFTC) can encourage ‘jumps’ in labour supply (e.g. From 10 to 30 hours) A’ A l H

  13. The Family: Harmony or Bargaining? • Unitary Model: • Family is a single unit with a single utility function and behaviour of all members chosen to maximise this. • Uf(c, li, lj) This implies: • Full income pooling • Symmetry of response to changes in other partners wage. • Neither Hold Collective Model: Family as a group of individuals who engage in (pareto-efficient) bargaining. This group of model allows one to extend models from just labour supply to looking at intra-household allocations of welfare.

  14. Putting it together… hi = f(wi,wj, t, b, yi, yj, fi, fj, c, r) t = tax system b = benefit system f = fixed costs r = real interest rate  Analysis of Labour supply can’t be done by a simple OLS regression of hours on wages because of the complexity of the budget constraint and substitution over time and within the household.

  15. Econometric Issues (1)… • You have data – a cross section of hours, wages and demographic characteristics. But theres a problem... • People have different preferences for work/leisure. • Those who like work are likely to work longer hours. • They are also likely to work harder, engage in training more, have tried harder at school and are probably more able. •  Spurious positive correlation between hours and wages • If taxes exhibit increasing marginal rates, those working longer hours will face higher marginal rates and have lower net wages. •  Spurious negative correlation between hours and wages

  16. Econometric Issues (2)… • ‘Second Generation’ models attempted to account for the downward bias induced by increasing marginal rates of tax. • very carefully modelled the tax system. • assume utility maximising and rational behaviour. • People bunch at the ‘kinks’ as marginal rates change. • Desired labour supply below kink at post-kink tax rate, and above kink at pre-kink tax rate. • When you combine this with a linear labour supply model • Restricts so that must estimate a positive uncompensated wage elasticity. H = α + βW + γY

  17. Econometric Issues (3)… • Solutions: • Use time series changes in wages (potentially a panel data series). • Preferably have exogenous reforms – e.g. Reduction of top rates of income tax, introduction of E.I.T.C. • Remember to control for aggregate preference changes (e.g. Social acceptability of women working). • E.G Blundell, Duncan & Meghir (1998) • Avoid modelling the complex tax system by using only women paying basic rate (nearly linear budget constraint). • Avoid preference problem by making use of changes in income distribution and tax reform in the 1980s. • Makes use in differential changes in post-tax wages for different cohorts and educational groups.

  18. Econometric Issues (4)… • Solutions: • Treat labour supply as discrete (e.g. full time, part time, not work) and estimate income at these points using full tax and benefit system. • E.G Meghir & Phillips (2008) • Men have a 1-0 choice of working or not, with income in work estimated as a weighted average of income at various hours points. • Use predicted wages for both non-workers and workers to account for (spurious) correlation of hours of work and pre-tax wages due to preferences. • Use the differential trends across regions in wages and housing benefits (out of work income) as exogenous changes in work incentives.

  19. Elasticity Estimates (Female)

  20. Elasticity Estimates (Male)

  21. Other aspects of Labour Supply • So far we have focused on hours but what about other aspects of labour supply? • intensity of effort (payment by results) • effort to seek promotion • investment in skills, education and complimentary capital • If substitution is easier for effort/investment than for work-hours  hours elasticities underestimate welfare cost of taxation. • Problem: we cannot measure effort...

  22. Taxable Income Elasticity (1) • ... but we can measure income. • Income reflects both hours of work and effort per hour. • It is a proxy for total effort. • Two measures: • Broad Income – reflects changes in effort. • Taxable Income – reflects changes in effort but also shifts in income from taxable to non-taxable forms (tax avoidance) and tax evasion. • Reallocation of income also entails welfare costs, and of course, revenue implications.

  23. Taxable Income Elasticity (2) • Main method of calculating taxable income elasticities is difference-in-differences. • Two groups – one affected by a change in tax rates (H), the other not (L). • Elasticity = difference in % change in income. • Elasticity = ΔlnEH – ΔlnEL. • Δln(1-tH) - Δln(1-tL)

  24. Taxable Income Elasticity (3) • Problems with this methodology: • Mean Reversion • E = μ + αt + Xi’β +Uit • Some people in group H likely to have transitory high income, and vice versa. •  Revert to mean: expect high income to fall, low income to rise. •  Estimates of elasticity will be downwardly biased. • General Equilibrium • Labour of different prices is probably labour of different ‘types’ to some extent. Increased supply of those benefiting from tax cut (e.g. High skilled) will depress price of this ‘type’, reducing income. •  Estimates of elasticity will be downwardly biased.

  25. Taxable Income Elasticity (4) • Problems with this methodology: • Secular Trends in Skills prices • The price of various types of Labour may be changing for reasons other than tax reforms – e.g. trade or technological change. •  Varies, but in 1980s/1990s, elasticity will be upwardly biased. • Timing • If a tax rise (or cut) is announced, people will bring forward (or put back) income if they have such flexibility – e.g. Bonuses, dividends, capital gains. •  Estimates of elasticity upwardly biased unless account for these ‘timing’ effects.

  26. Elasticity Estimates

  27. Reforming Support for Lone Parents • Fewer than 60% of lone parents employed versus about 70% of mothers in couples: • Similar number of lone parents working 16+ hours. • But far fewer lone parents working 1 – 15 hours. Why? • No incentive to do so: • Income Support is Tapered away at 100% above earnings of £20 a week. • Housing Benefit and Council tax have tapers of 65% and 20%. When combined with income tax, tapers of over 95%. • No working tax credit (WTC) unless you work 16 hours per week.

  28. The Gains of Labour... .. are less for lone parents for 8 – 16 hours.

  29. .. and they face high effective tax rates

  30. Making ‘mini jobs’ Pay... • IFS and One Parent Families were asked by the Joseph Rowntree Foundation to look at ways of improve work incentives. • Giving WTC to lone parents working less than 16 hours per week. • Increasing the earnings disregard for income support and other means-tested benefits. • Reducing the taper rate on income support and other means-tested benefits. • - does more to encourage jobs with higher rates of pay. • - but administratively more burdensome as still need to know about small changes in income.

  31. Modelling Lone Parent’s Labour Supply... • Model used is: • estimated using repeated cross sections from the Family Resources Survey (FRS) – roughly 17,000 lone parents. • uses cross-sectional and time-series (policy reforms) variation in work incentives. • discrete choice: not work, 1 – 15 hours, 16 – 23, 24 – 29, 30 – 37, 38+. • income estimated at each of these choices. • they take up all benefits and tax credits entitled to. • use of childcare determined by family circumstances and hours – not price or subsidies. • repeatedly draw a prediction for each lone parent to get weights for each hours choice, before and after reform.

  32. Results WTC reduces average hours, offsetting extra tax credits. Increased disregards also encourage 16 – 30 hours work, increasing average hours and earnings.

  33. Conclusions (1) • Income and substitution effects can give some important insights (e.g. the ‘10p tax’). • - But non-convexities and fixed costs means can see ‘jumps’ in Labour supply in response to reforms. • Compensated versus uncompensated elasticities • - Tax rises have an ambiguous effect on labour supply and revenue but always entail deadweight loss. • Estimation of model made difficult due to complex budget constraint and unobserved preferences for work. • - Use exogenous variation in incentives due to secular wage changes or tax reforms as basis of estimation.

  34. Conclusions (2) • Estimated responsiveness varies by group • - Low for men • - Higher for women, particularly lone parents • - Participation decision particularly sensitive • Taxable Income Elasticities • - Picks up effort and reallocation of income • - But problems if simple diff-in-difference techniques used. • Example: Lone Parents and Mini-jobs. • - Lone parents face poor incentives to enter work at low hours. • - Reforms to benefits and tax credits can have a big impact on labour supply for this sensitive group.

  35. Main Readings C. Meghir & D. Phillips (2008) – Labour Supply and Taxes http://www.ifs.org.uk/wps/wp0804.pdf K. Bell, M. Brewer & D. Phillips (2007) – Lone Parents and Mini-jobs http://www.jrf.org.uk/bookshop/eBooks/2110-lone-parents-minijobs.pdf

  36. Additional References Aaberge, Colombino, Strom (1999) "Labour Supply in Italy: An Empirical Analysis of Joint Household Decisions with Taxes and Quantity Constraints", Journal of Applied Econometrics, Vol 14. No 4. Ashenfelter & Heckman (1974) "The Estimation of Income and Substitution Effects in a model of Family Labor supply", Econometrica, Vol 42, No 1 Blomquist & Newey (2002), "Nonparametric Estimation with Nonlinear Budget Constraints", Ecometrica, Vol. 70, No. 6 Blundell, Duncan, Meghir, (1992), "Taxation in Empricial Labour Supply Models: Lone Mothers in the UK", The Economic Journal, Vol 102, No 411 Blundell, Duncan, Meghir (1998) "Estimating Labor Supply Responses using Tax Reforms, Econometrica, Vol 66, No 4 Bourguignon & Magnac (1990) "Labor Supply and Taxation in France", The Journal of Human Resources, Vol 25, No 3 Cogan (1981), "Fixed Costs and Labor Supply", Econometrica, Vol 49, No 4 Feldstein (1995), "The Effects of Marginal Tax Rates on Taxable Income: a Panel study of the 1986 Tax Reform Act", Journal of Political Economy, Vol 103, No 3 Goolsbee (1999) "Evidence on the High-Income Laffer Curve from Six Decades of Tax Reform", Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Vol 1999, No 2 Gruber & Saez (2000) "The Elasticity of Taxable Income: Evidence and Implications", NBER Working Paper Series Hausman (1981), Labour Supply: How Taxes affect Economic Behaviour", Tax and the Economy, Brookings Institute

More Related