1 / 36

Intensity Based Models Advanced Methods of Risk Management Umberto Cherubini

Intensity Based Models Advanced Methods of Risk Management Umberto Cherubini. In this lecture you will learn Extract default intensity from market data Model the dynamics of the intensity of default and the credit spread Calibrate the recovery rate from the CDS and the bond markets

fraley
Télécharger la présentation

Intensity Based Models Advanced Methods of Risk Management Umberto Cherubini

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Intensity Based Models Advanced Methods of Risk Management Umberto Cherubini

  2. In this lecture you will learn Extract default intensity from market data Model the dynamics of the intensity of default and the credit spread Calibrate the recovery rate from the CDS and the bond markets Extend the model to portfolios Learning Objectives

  3. In the reduced form models, default probability and recovery rate (LGD) are modelled based on statistical assumptions instead of an economic model of the firm. The modelling techniques that are used are very close to those applied in insurance mathematics, specifying the frequency of occurrence of the event (default probability) and the severity of loss in case the event takes place (loss given default) These models use then the concept of intensity and for this reason are also called intensity based Reduced form models

  4. Denote, in a structural model, Q the probability of survival of the obligor after the maturity of the obligation, (the default probability is then DP = 1 – Q) and LGD the loss given default figure. Then, the credit spread is given by Credit Spread = – ln[1 – (1 – Q )LGD]/(T – t) Assume now the most extreme case in which all the exposure is lost (LGD = 1). We have Credit Spread = – ln[Q]/(T – t) Models from survival analysis (actuarial science) can help design the credit spread. Credit spread and survival analysis

  5. Assume the default event to be drawn from a Poisson distribution (remember that it describes the probability of a countable set of events in a period of time). The Poisson distribution is characterized by a single parameter, called intensity. The probability that no event takes place before time T (in our case meaning survival probability beyond that)is given by the formula Prob( > T) = exp (–  (T - t)) The simplest model

  6. Applying the survival probability function Q = Prob( > T) = exp (–  (T - t)) to the credit spread formula (again under the assumption LGD = 1) Credit Spread = – ln[Q]/(T – t) we get Credit Spread =  Constant intensity model

  7. Intensity  denotes the probability of an event in an infinitesimal interval of time. The expected time before occurrence of the event is 1/. Differently from structural models, the default event comes as a “surprise”. Technically, it is said that default is an inaccessible time. The intensity corresponds to the concept of instantaneous forward rate in interest rate models. Intensity vs structural

  8. If the intensity parameter is not fixed, but changes stochastically with time, the model is called Cox model (or double stochastic models) For every maturity we can consider an average intensity (t,T) and the credit spread curve will be Credit Spread(t,T) = (t,T) Notice that the relationship between , that is the instantaneous intensity, and the average intensity is the same as that between instantaneous spot rate and yield to maturity in term structure models Cox models

  9. Assume the dynamics of default intensity is described by a diffusive process like d (t) = k( – (t))dt + dz(t) where setting  = 0, 0.5 deliver standard affine term structure models for the credit spread Debt(t,T) = v(t,T)exp(A(T-t) - B(T -t) (t)) with A and B the affine functions in Vasicek ( = 0) or Cox Ingersoll Ross ( = 0.5) models Affine intensity models

  10. If we assume positive recovery rate (and so LGD < 1) and independence between interest rate in default intensity we can easily extend the analysis. Denote  the recovery rate and compute Debt(t,T; )=v(t,T)[Prob( > T)+ Prob(  T)] Debt(t,T; )=  v(t,T) +(1-) Prob( >T)v(t,T) Debt(t,T; 0)= Prob( >T)v(t,T), from which... Debt(t,T; )=  v(t,T) +(1-) D(t,T; 0) The price is obtained as a portfolio of the risk free asset and a defaultable exposure with recovery rate zero. Positive recovery rate

  11. The spread of a BBB 10 exposure over the risk-free yield curve is 45 basis points. Assuming zero recovery rate we get Prob( >T) = exp (– .0045 10) = 0.955997 and the probability of default is 1 - 0.955997 = 4.4003% Assuming a 50% recovery rate we have Prob( >T) = [exp (– .0045 10) - ]/(1- ) = 0.911995 and default probability is 1 - 0.911995 = 8.8005% Default probabilities

  12. The other point involved in modelling the expected loss refers to the recovery rate. This topic is particularly involved, and the research on the subject is not very developed. In particular, the point is how to recover the value of the recovery rate the dependence of recovery rate and default whether the recovery rate is computed with respect to face value or market value, or other Recovery rate

  13. In case the recovery rate is independent of the default probability expected loss can be computed using whatever distribution defined on the support between 0 and 1 Typical example is the beta distribution that is very often used to study the recovery from samples of defaults. Altman,Resti and Sironi find that the number of defaults and the amount of recovery are negatively correlated across business cycles Recovery rate and default

  14. Recovery of face value: it is the legal concept of recovery. Once in default, payments of interest is stopped and a fraction of principal is allocated to creditors Recovery of treasury: it refers to a fraction of a risk free bond (Treasury!!) with the same financial structure of the defaultable bond Recovery of market value: it refers to the market value of the bond prior to default Recovery of what?

  15. It is based on the idea of legal default. It is useful for corporate bonds. Moody’s compute the recovery rate as the ratio of the value of the bond on the secondary market one month after default and the face value. Technically, default should be considered at every time, assuming that the bond is substituted with a percentage of par. In practice, it can be approximated assuming payment of the recovery at maturity of the bond, as in the previous example. Recovery of face value

  16. It is based on the assumption that in case of default there is rescheduling. It is typical of sovereign risk applications in which case there is no formal bankruptcy procedure leading to recovery of fraction of par Typical example is the concept of “haircut” that is currently used in the current discussion on the sovereign debt crisis in the Euro area. Recovery of treasury

  17. It is considered as an approximation that makes the model easier to handle. In fact, it turns out that intensity can be modified by allowing for the intensity to be adjusted by LGD. Namely, in the simple constant intensity model, with intensity , one could adjust the intensity to * =  LGD. In a discrete time setting, the one-period interest rate (r +  LGD)/(1 –  LGD) Recovery of market value

  18. In 2005 Argentina offered a swap program of bonds defaulted in 2001 for two structures of bonds Discount bonds: maturity 12/2033, coupons 7.82% (capitalized until 12/2013). Exchange ratio 33.70% Par bonds: maturity 09/2038, lower coupons step up (2.26%, 3.38%, 4.74%) amortizing schedule 20 equal payments starting in the last 10 years. Exchange ratio: 100% The case of OPS Argentina

  19. The prices of the OPS bonds

  20. Argentina CDS

  21. Recovery: PAR

  22. Recovery: DISCOUNT

  23. Type: Discount Market price: 63.974 Fair Value: 151.12 EL (Face): 67.46 EL (Treasury): 87.22 Value (Face): 83.66 Value (Trs): 63.91 Recovery: 21.92% Type: Par Market price: 31.25 Fair Value: 91.22 EL (Face): 64.50 EL (Treasury): 59.22 Value (Face): 26.73 Value (Trs): 32.00 Recovery: 21.92 OPS bonds

  24. Assume we have a portfolio of exposures (for simplicity with the same LGD). We can distinguish between a very large number of exposures and a limited number of them. In a retail setting we are obviously interested in the former case, even though to set up the model we can focus on the latter one (around 50-100). We want define the probability of loss on the portfolio. We define Q(k) the probability of observing k defaults (Q(0) being survival probability of the portfolio). Expected loss is Portfolios of exposures

  25. Consider a credit derivative providing “protection” the first time that an element in the basket of obligations defaults. Assume the protection is extended up to time T. The value of the derivative is FTD = LGD v(t,T)(1 – Q(0)) Q(0) is the survival probability of all the names in the basket: Q(0) Q(1 > T, 2 > T…) “First-to-default” derivatives

  26. As an extension, consider a derivative providing protection on the first x defaults of the obligations in the basket. The value of the derivative will be “First-x-to-default” derivatives

  27. Evaluating basket credit derivatives and the credit risk of a portfolio requires to specify the joint distribution of defaults Q(x) This distribution depends on two elements Default probability of each obligation in the basket. The correlation (dependence) structure of defaults of the obligations in the portfolio. Probability Q(x) specification

  28. Hypotheses about individual exposures are Homogeneous pool of exposures (same default probability) Heterogeneous pool of exposures (different default probabilities) Hypotheses about dependence structure are Indipendent defaults Multivariate reduced form models (Marshall Olkin) Copula functions Factor copulas (conditionally indipendent defaults) Models for Q(x)

  29. If we assume the defaults to be independent the most obvious choices for the joint probability are Binomial distribution Poisson distribution Indipendent defaults

  30. Poisson model is particularly useful because it allows immediate extension of reduced form models to the multivariate setting. The indipendence hypothesis implies that Q(0) = Q(1 > T, 2 > T…) = Q(1 > T) Q(2 > T)… and, in intensity based models Q(1 > T) Q( 2 > T)…= exp[– (1 + 2 +…)(T – t)] We then obtain a porfolio intensity as the sum of individual intensities  = 1 + 2 +… Portfolio intensity

  31. Remember that the value of the a first-to-default swap is given by FTD = LGD v(t,T)(1 – Q(0)) In the independent default case we get then LGDv(t,T)(1 – exp[– (T – t)]) = LGDv(t,T)(1 – exp[– (1 + 2 +…)(T – t)]) The problem is to extend this model to the case in which defaults are dependent. The value of a first-to-default

  32. Marshall Olkin distribution is the natural extension of Poisson distribution to the multivariate case. Assume a case with two exposures. According to Marshall Olkin distribution we have Q(1 > T, 2 > T) = exp[– (1 + 2 + 12)(T – t)] where 12 is the intensity of an event “killing” both the obligations. The correlation between the survival times is 12 = 12 /(1 + 2 + 12) Marshall Olkin distribution

  33. The idea behind Marshall Olkin distribution is that several shocks affect subset of the obligations in the portfolio. The problem is that one may conceive a very high number of such shock, making calibration of the model unfeasible. Generally the specification is proposed is with a unique common factor, and the intensity is Portfolio intensity

  34. In Marshall Olkin distribution each exposure in the portfolio is subject to idiosyncratic shocks and shocks that are common to other exposures. The shock that triggers default of all exposures is the ideal representation of a systemic event. Notice that since in the Marshall-Olkin model all events (idiosyncratic and common) are independent, the models does not allow for contagion In a possible extension, contagion can be introduced with dependence between idiosyncratic and common shocks, Intensity risk and contagion

More Related