1 / 44

GY460 Techniques of Spatial Analysis

GY460 Techniques of Spatial Analysis. Lecture 6: Probabilistic choice models. Steve Gibbons. Introduction. Sometimes useful to model individual firm, or other agents choices over discrete alternatives Choice of transport mode Choice of firm location amongst regions

gunda
Télécharger la présentation

GY460 Techniques of Spatial Analysis

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. GY460 Techniques of Spatial Analysis Lecture 6: Probabilistic choice models Steve Gibbons

  2. Introduction • Sometimes useful to model individual firm, or other agents choices over discrete alternatives • Choice of transport mode • Choice of firm location amongst regions • Choice of cities or country to migrate to • Theoretical framework • Random utility model • Empirical methods: • Micro: Probit, logit, multinomial logit • Aggregate: Poisson, OLS, gravity

  3. The “Random Utility” choice model

  4. Random Utility Model • RUM underlies economic interpretation of discrete choice models. Developed by Daniel McFadden for econometric applications • see JoEL January 2001 for Nobel lecture; also Manski (2001) Daniel McFadden and the Econometric Analysis of Discrete Choice, Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 103(2), 217-229 • Preferences are functions of biological taste templates, experiences, other personal characteristics • Some of these are observed, others unobserved • Allows for taste heterogeneity • Discussion below is in terms of individual utility (e.g. migration, transport mode choice) but similar reasoning applies to firm choices

  5. Random Utility Model • Individual i’s utility from a choice j can be decomposed into two components: • Vij is deterministic – common to everyone, given the same characteristics and constraints • representative tastes of the population e.g. effects of time and cost on travel mode choice • ij is random • reflects idiosyncratic tastes of i and unobserved attributes of choice j

  6. Random Utility Model • Vij is a function of attributes of alternative j (e.g. price and time) and observed consumer and choice characteristics. • We are interested in finding , ,  • Lets forget about z now for simplicity

  7. RUM and binary choices • Consider two choices e.g. bus or car • We observe whether an individual uses one or the other • Define • What is the probability that we observe an individual choosing to travel by bus? • Assume utility maximisation • Individual chooses bus (y=1) rather than car (y=0) if utility of commuting by bus exceeds utility of commuting by car

  8. RUM and binary choices • So choose bus if • So the probability that we observe an individual choosing bus travel is

  9. The linear probability model • Assume probability depends linearly on observed characteristics (price and time) • Then you can estimate by linear regression • Where is the “dummy variable” for mode choice (1 if bus, 0 if car) • Other consumer and choice characteristics can be included (the zs in the first slide in this section)

  10. The linear probability model • Unfortunately his has some undesirable properties 1 Linear regression line 0

  11. Non-linear probability model • Better for probability function to have a shape something like: 1 0

  12. Probits and logits • Common assumptions: • Cumulative normal distribution function – “Probit” • Logistic function – “Logit” • Estimation by maximum likelihood

  13. Example • McFadden, D. (1974) The Measurement of Urban Travel Demand, Journal of Public Economics, 3 • Methods of commuting in San Francisco Bay area

  14. Example 1 McFadden (1974) car versus bus commute modes in SF Bay area

  15. Multiple choices and the “multinomial logit”

  16. Multiple choices • We often want to think about many more than two choices • Choice of regional location • Choice of transport mode with many alternatives • Choice amongst a sample of schools • How can we extend the binary choice logit model? • Random Utility model extends to many choices • Choose choice k if utility higher than for all other choices

  17. Multinomial logit (1) • Again we need to assume some distribution for the unobserved factor  • One type of distribution (extreme value) gives a simple solution for the probability that choice k is made: • This is a generalisation of the logit model with many alternatives = “multinomial logit” or “conditional logit”

  18. Multinomial logit (2) • Recall: Vij is a linear function of observed characteristics of the individuals and their choices. e.g. for travel mode choice • Parameters estimated: • For an individual characteristic that is common across choices (e.g. income, gender): one parameter per choice • For at least one choice this is zero (base case). • For a characteristic which varies only across choices e.g. price of transport: one parameter common across choices

  19. Example: Value of time • MNL models used to estimate “value of travel time” with from observed commuter behaviour • Three transport choices: bus (0), train (1), car (2) • Choosing bus as the base case:

  20. Example 1: Value of time • For example, from Truong and Hensher, Economic Journal, 95 (1985) p. 15 for bus/train/car choices in Sydney 1982

  21. Example 2: immigration • Scott, Coomes and Izyumov, (2005)The Location Choice of Employment-Based Immigrants among U.S. Metro Areas. Journal of Regional Science 45(1) 113-145 • Estimate the impact of metropolitan area characteristics on destination choice for US migrants in 1995 • 298 destination MSAs

  22. Example 2: immigration Source: Scott, Coomes et al (note: they also report models which include individual Xs)

  23. The independence of irrelevant alternatives problem (IIA) and the nested logit model

  24. Multinomial logit and “IIA” • Many applications in economic and geographical journals (and other research areas) • The multinomial logit model is the workhorse of multiple choice modelling in all disciplines. Easy to compute • But it has a drawback

  25. Independence of Irrelevant Alternatives • Consider market shares • Red bus 20% • Blue bus 20% • Train 60% • IIA assumes that if red bus company shuts down, the market shares become • Blue bus 20% + 5% = 25% • Train 60% + 15% = 75% • Because the ratio of blue bus trips to train trips must stay at 1:3

  26. Independence of Irrelevant Alternatives • Model assumes that ‘unobserved’ attributes of all alternatives are perceived as equally similar • But will people unable to travel by red bus really switch to travelling by train? • Most likely outcome is (assuming supply of bus seats is elastic) • Blue bus: 40% • Train: 60% • This failure of multinomial/conditional logit models is called the • Independence of Irrelevant Alternatives assumption (IIA)

  27. Independence of Irrelevant Alternatives • It is easy to see why this is: • Ratio of probabilities of choosing k (e.g. red bus) and another choice l (e.g. train) is just • All other choices drop out of this odds ratio • There are models that overcome this, e.g…

  28. Nested Logit Model • Multinomial logit model can be generalised to relax IIA assumption • Nested Logit (Nested Multinomial Logit) Public transport (2) Car (1) Bus (3) Train (4) • Characteristics of Bus and Train affect decision of whether to use Car or Public Transport • Estimate by sequential logits…

  29. Nested Logit Model • Value placed on choices available in second stage (3,4) enter into calculation of choice probabilities in first stage (2)… • Logit for bus versus train to estimate V3 and V4 • Define the ‘Inclusive Value’ of public transport as • Estimate logit model for Car (1) versus Public (2) using:

  30. Example: Transport mode choice • Asensio, J., Transport Mode Choice by Commuters to Barcelona’s CBD, Urban Studies, 39(10), 2002 • Travel mode for suburban commuters • Sample of 1381 commuters from a travel survey • Records mode of transport and other individual characteristics Public transport Private car Bus Train

  31. Example: Transport mode choice • Asensio, J., Transport Mode Choice by Commuters to Barcelona’s CBD, Urban Studies, 39(10), 2002 • Some selected coefficients • We don’t know the units of measurement, but how much more valuable is time saved car than time saved by public transport?

  32. Other discrete choice applications • Firm location choices e.g. Head, K. and T.Mayer seminar reading (2004), Market Potential and the Location of Japanese Investment in the European Union, Review of Economics and Statistics, 86(4) 959-972 • School choice (e.g. Barro, L. (2002) School choice through relocation: evidence from the Washington, D.C. area, Journal of Public Economics, 86 p.155-189 • Migration destinations • Residential choice

  33. Aggregate choice models

  34. Micro and aggregated choice models • Micro level logit choice models often have aggregated equivalents • i.e. if you only have choice characteristics, you could use a choice-level regression of the proportion of individuals making each choice on the choice characteristics • Obviously log(n_k) would work too (why?)

  35. Micro and aggregated choice models • In fact, a Poisson model on aggregated data gives exactly the same coefficient estimates as the conditional logit model • Which is based on ML estimation of • See Guimaraes et al Restats (2003) • though this equivalence was known before this ‘discovery’ • Here’s an example…

  36. Data (295 i’s 3 j’s)

  37. Conditional logit Conditional (fixed-effects) logistic regression Number of obs = 885 LR chi2(1) = 129.65 Prob > chi2 = 0.0000 Log likelihood = -259.26785 Pseudo R2 = 0.2000 ------------------------------------------------------------------------------ choice | Coef. Std. Err. z P>|z| [95% Conf. Interval] -------------+---------------------------------------------------------------- x | .0999331 .0091997 10.86 0.000 .081902 .1179642 ------------------------------------------------------------------------------

  38. Simpler data

  39. Poisson Poisson regression Number of obs = 3 LR chi2(1) = 129.65 Prob > chi2 = 0.0000 Log likelihood = -9.3973119 Pseudo R2 = 0.8734 ------------------------------------------------------------------------------ n | Coef. Std. Err. z P>|z| [95% Conf. Interval] -------------+---------------------------------------------------------------- x | .0999331 .0091997 10.86 0.000 .081902 .1179642 _cons | 3.364614 .1450806 23.19 0.000 3.080262 3.648967 ------------------------------------------------------------------------------

  40. OLS . reg lnp x Source | SS df MS Number of obs = 3 -------------+------------------------------ F( 1, 1) = 370.23 Model | 1.32738687 1 1.32738687 Prob > F = 0.0331 Residual | .003585331 1 .003585331 R-squared = 0.9973 -------------+------------------------------ Adj R-squared = 0.9946 Total | 1.3309722 2 .665486102 Root MSE = .05988 ------------------------------------------------------------------------------ lnp | Coef. Std. Err. t P>|t| [95% Conf. Interval] -------------+---------------------------------------------------------------- x | .101293 .0052644 19.24 0.033 .034403 .168183 _cons | -2.339238 .06295 -37.16 0.017 -3.139094 -1.539383 ------------------------------------------------------------------------------

  41. Aggregate v micro choice models • Hence, there’s little point in using conditional logit if you only have choice-characteristics • Conditional/multinomial logit is good if you have individual and group-level characteristics • The aggregated OLS version gives rise to “Spatial interaction” models of flows between origins and destinations • = Gravity models • Widely applied (generally a-theoretically) in migration, trade and commuting applications • e.g. See Head (2003) Gravity for beginners

  42. Gravity/spatial interaction/migration/trade models • Flow from place j to place k modelled as • Typically characteristics of destination and source include some measure of “attraction” e.g. population mass (or “market potential” in trade models) wages (endogenous) • And measure of the cost in moving between place j and d (e.g. log distance) • Hence gravity – after Newton

  43. Gravity/spatial interaction/migration/trade models • Strong distance decay effects • Typical elasticities -0.5 to -2.0 • Even for internet site visits!: see Blum and Goldfarb (2006) Journal of International Economics • Trade literature has many examples • Disdier and Head (2003) The Puzzling Persistence Of The Distance Effect On Bilateral Trade, Review of Economics and Statistics • Finds mean distance elasticity of -0.9 from about 1500 studies

  44. Conclusion • Generally possible to model ‘choices’ as discrete, or as flows • Discrete choice models offer the advantage of • Including micro-level (individual/firm) level characteristics • An underlying structural model (RUM) • Aggregate flow models • Simpler to compute • No need for distributional assumptions necessary for maximum likelihood (nonlinear) methods • A can’t separate individual from aggregate factors

More Related