1 / 25

Prof. Dr. Friedrich Schneider Institut für Volkswirtschaftslehre http://www.econ.jku.at/schneider

Prof. Dr. Friedrich Schneider Institut für Volkswirtschaftslehre http://www.econ.jku.at/schneider . Recht und Ökonomie ( Law and Economics ). LVA-Nr.: 239.203 W S 2012/13 ( 7 ) Criminal Law ( Strafrecht ). Overview. Introduction Rational Decision Making Market for Crime

ilori
Télécharger la présentation

Prof. Dr. Friedrich Schneider Institut für Volkswirtschaftslehre http://www.econ.jku.at/schneider

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Prof. Dr. Friedrich Schneider Institut für Volkswirtschaftslehre http://www.econ.jku.at/schneider Recht und Ökonomie (Law and Economics) LVA-Nr.: 239.203 WS 2012/13 (7) Criminal Law (Strafrecht) Law and Economics

  2. Overview • Introduction • Rational Decision Making • Market for Crime • Incentives • Risk and Deterrence • Further Topic: Death Penalty Law and Economics

  3. 1. Introduction • Crime causes costs: • economic problem of optimal allocation of resources. • Empirical evidence for influence of economic variables on the frequency of crime. • Employ economic modelling and econometric techniques to analyse relationship between: • crime, • deterrence (fine/sentence), and • economic situation. Law and Economics

  4. 2. Rational Decision Making • If: (expected) utility (EU) from crime > (expected) utility (EU) from alternative time use (like legal work!) • Crime will be committed when EU > 0 • EU = p * U(Yi – f) + (1 – p) * [U(Yi) – U(YL)] , where: • p … probability of sentencing; • U … von Neumann-Morgenstern utility function ∂U(.) / ∂Y>0 ; • Yi … income from illegal action, • YL … income from legal action, • f … fine (or imprisonment) in case of sentencing. Law and Economics

  5. 3. Market for Crime • Equilibrium level of crime is determined by • Supply (S): positive relationship between π and C: the higher the profit (π) resulting from criminal act (C), the higher the incentive to commit the crime. • Demand (D): negative relationship between π and C: the more criminal acts, the higher the sensitivity of (potential) victims, profits of criminal acts decline. Law and Economics

  6. 3. Market for Crime (cont.) • In all countries the optimal level of crime is greater than zero! • “… crime is a normal social phenomenon whose complete abolishment by government is neither possible nor desirable.” (Gary Becker, 1968). • Optimal level of crime is where: • marginal cost of deterrence are equal to their marginal revenue (return). Law and Economics

  7. 3. Market for Crime (cont.) • Consequences of (equal) increases in wealth (or income): • more protective measures, D declines. • Consequences of increases in inequality: • D, and possibly also S, increase. • Total effect: • crime may increase despite more protection! Law and Economics

  8. 4. Crime Incentives • Negative incentives: • increase probability of sentencing, and • increase sentences or fines. • Positive incentives: • increase wages, • reduce unemployment, • increase social benefits, and • improve rehabilitation. Law and Economics

  9. 4. Crime Incentives (cont.) • Why did crime rates (unexpectedly) fall in the USA during the 1990s? • Major factors according to the study of Levitt 2003: • increase in the police force, • more inmates in jails, • reduced consumption of crack/other drugs, • legalisation of abortions, and • prevention programs. Law and Economics

  10. 4. Crime Incentives (cont.) • Many studies showing a variety of influences of variables follow from the economic model of crime: • unemployment, • job availability, • inequality in income (distribution), • police intensity, • risk of sanctioning, • demography (age, different nationalities, ‘racial composition’), • drug consumption, and • migration. Law and Economics

  11. 5. Risk and Deterrence Probability of sanction, fine, and imprisonment • Individuals may be • risk averse, risk neutral or risk lovers, depending on their economic and sociological situation. • Important: product of probability of sanction (p) and (expected) sentence (f)  p times f is relevant! • Increasing f and reducing p is, in general, more efficient. • Fines are, in general, preferred to imprisonment, again being more efficient. • Labour resources lost plus cost of jailing. Law and Economics

  12. 5. Risk and Deterrence (cont.) Imprisonment: • If individuals are risk averse, raising imprisonment terms allows to lower probability of sanctioning more than proportionally. • Expected prison terms fall, thus cost to society decrease. • If individuals are risk loving, raising imprisonment terms allows to lower probability of sanctioning less than proportionally. • Expected prison terms rise, thus cost to society increase. Law and Economics

  13. 5. Risk and Deterrence (cont.) Some Empirical Results according to U.S. studies from 2005: • Estimated cost of reducing property crime by 1 %: • more police officers: USD 34.0 million in a district (state); • more prison sentences: USD 3.2 million (court costs); • longer prison sentences: USD 2.4 million (prison costs). Law and Economics

  14. 5. Risk and Deterrence (cont.) Some Empirical Results according to U.S. studies from 2005: • Elasticities of property crimes (pc): a 10 % increase of … • police officers reduces pc by3.2 %; • rate of imprisonment reduces pc by4.8 %; • length of imprisonment reduces pc by8.5 %; • increase in unemployment increases pc by 4.6 %. • Larger impact on burglary and robbery. • Smaller impact on theft. Law and Economics

  15. 5.1. Risk and Deterrence: Draconian Punishments Draconian punishments may not be appropriate, because: • criminals lack income or wealth; • judges may hesitate to convict (death penalty!); • increased litigation leading to higher legal cost; • of perverse incentives: steal bread and shoot baker; • of disrespect for the law being ‘unjust’. Law and Economics

  16. 6. Economics of Crime - Further Topic: Death Penalty • Limitations to economic analyses of crime. • Capital punishment and deterrence. • Addictive drugs and crime. • Criminalization of addictive drugs. • Plus: • in-depth analyses of all of the (economic) factors described above influencing criminal activities. Law and Economics

  17. 6. Further Topic: Death Penalty (cont.) • Article in the NY Times (Nov. 18, 2007): • Does death penalty save lives? (source: https://www.nytimes.com/2007/11/18/us/18deter.html?pagewanted=all) • Some facts: USA, 2003: • 16,500 homicides; • 144 death sentences; • 3,400 inmates on death row; • 65 executions. Law and Economics

  18. 6. Further Topic: Death Penalty6.1. Death Penalty as Deterrent? ‘Survey’ by DONOHUE & WOLFERS (2006) • Main results: • "The view that the death penalty deters is still the product of belief, not evidence ... On balance, the evidence suggests that the death penalty may increase the murder rate." • When D&W compared death penalty states with non-death penalty states, they found no evidenceof any effect of executions on murder rates, either up or down. Law and Economics

  19. 6. Further Topic: Death Penalty6.2. Death Penalty and Theories of ‚Deterrence‘ • Economic theory: • raise price for murder. • Behavioural (psychological) theory: • small likelihood is treated as zero probability, or • low frequency with great publicity deters. • Sociological theory: • executions reduce value of life, implies ‘brutalisation’ leads to more homicides. Law and Economics

  20. 6. Further Topic: Death Penalty6.3. US History of Murders & Executions Results from Donohue and Wolfers (2006): • Aggregate time series show no clear correlation between homicides and executions (20th century): • 1900-1910: no correlation. • 1910-1920: executions down, homicides up. • 1920-1940: both increase. • 1940-1960: both decrease. • 1970-1975: moratorium on executions, homicides up. • 1975-1990: executions up, homicides remain high. • 1990-2000: executions up, homicides down. Law and Economics

  21. 6. Further Topic: Death Penalty6.4. Comparison of six US-States without Death Penalty in USA Results from Donohue and Wolfers (2006): • Period analyzed: 1960 – 2000. • Abolition or moratorium and reinstatement in all other states. • Result: very similar movement in the six States to the USA overall figures, high positive correlation between the two time series! • Conclusion: there must be other factors at work! Law and Economics

  22. 6. Further Topic: Death Penalty6.5. Are other Factors important? • DEZHBAKHSH & SHEPHERD (2004) focus in their before/after comparison only on States that abolished or that adopted death penalty: • abolition: 10 – 20 % increase in homicides; • reinstatement: 5 – 10 % decrease in homicides. • But: ‘control group’ of States that had no change showed very similar effects! • No difference to States that experienced changes! Law and Economics

  23. 6. Further Topic: Death Penalty6.6. How to Measure ‘Death Penalty’? Measures for ‘death penalty’: • Binary variable – death penalty law? Y/N. • Persons sentenced to death (always annual data). • Persons executed. • Persons sentenced to death (per 100,000 inhabitants). • Persons sentenced to death (per total sentences). • Persons executed (per 100,000 inhabitants). • Persons executed (per 1,000 prisoners). • Persons executed (per prisoners on death row). • Persons on death row. Law and Economics

  24. 6. Further Topic: Death Penalty6.7. Executions: Further Results Not very robust results: • When introducing year-fixed-effects into the DEZHBAKHSH & SHEPHERD (2004) study, the effect of executions becomes statistically insignificant! • D. & S. use absolute numbers of executions –heavy influence of Texas: omission of Texas has the same effect as above! • Using executions per 1,000 prisoner or per 100,000 residents again has the same effect! Law and Economics

  25. 6. Further Topic: Death Penalty 6.8. Conclusion on Deterrence Effect of Death Penalty • Empirical evidence is (very) inconclusive. • Thus it cannot be employed to justify ‘death penalty’. • Should one turn to more ‘philosophical’ reasons and justifications? • E.g. the government must act on the basis of a moral obligation since inactivity (‘omission’) may endanger its citizens? Law and Economics

More Related