1 / 23

Chapter 12 Monopoly and Regulation

Chapter 12 Monopoly and Regulation. Polar extreme of perfect competition is a market with only one firm supplying output Called a monopoly Firm with no substitutes (competition) for its output This chapter discusses barriers to entry as cause of monopolies

lilia
Télécharger la présentation

Chapter 12 Monopoly and Regulation

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Chapter 12 Monopoly and Regulation • Polar extreme of perfect competition is a market with only one firm supplying output • Called a monopoly • Firm with no substitutes (competition) for its output • This chapter discusses barriers to entry as cause of monopolies • We then develop short-run price and output determination for a profit-maximizing monopoly • We derive relationship of a monopoly’s price with market elasticity of demand • We investigate long-run equilibrium for monopolies

  2. Barriers to Entry • Cause of a monopoly is barriers (obstacles) to entry • Barriers to entry are anything that allow existing firms to earn pure profits • One type of a legal monopoly is established by a state or federal government awarding only one firm an exclusive franchise to provide a commodity • Government may do so because there are increasing returns to scale over a wide range of output • If society deems that unrestricted competition among firms in an industry is undesirable • Government may establish a legal monopoly by granting a firm exclusive rights to operate • For example, patents • Technological barriers to entry may result when a firm’s technology results in decreasing LAC over a wide range of output, knowledge of a low-cost productive technique, or control of a strategic resource • Termed natural monopolies • Because market forces establish monopoly

  3. Price and Output Determination • Objective of monopolies • Maximize profits • First determine profit-maximizing output • Then determine price required to sell output • Alternatively, they can first determine profit-maximizing price • Then from market demand curve determine level of output that can be sold at this price • Resulting profit-maximizing price/output combination will be the same • Regardless of which method is employed • Market demand curve is downward sloping • If a monopoly reduces output, price it receives for this output will increase

  4. Price and Output Determination • Monopoly has control over market price • A price maker • Consider following linear market demand curve • AR = p = a – bQ • TR = (AR)Q = pQ = aQ – bQ2 • MR = ∂TR/∂Q = a – 2bQ = a – bQ – bQ = AR - bQ • Where a, b > 0 • For a linear demand curve, MR is twice as steep as AR • Illustrated in Figure 12.1

  5. Figure 12.1 Linear market demand curve

  6. Price and Output Determination • In Figure 12.1, AR is falling as firm increases output • Because consumers are willing and able to purchase more of commodity at lower level of AR (price) • Falling AR implies that MR is below it • MR is equal to AR plus adjustment factor, -bQ • Given -b <0 (falling AR), then MR <AR • For a given level of output, MR <AR • For a firm to sell an additional unit of output it must lower its price on all units to be sold, not just on additional units • Adjustment factor, -bQ, accounts for this condition • For each additional output sold, price falls by -b • Multiplying this fall in price by number of units sold • Results in adjustment to AR for determining MR

  7. Profit Maximization • Mathematically, short-run profit is maximized by • F.O.C. is • ∂/∂Q = ∂TR/∂Q = ∂STC/ ∂Q = 0 = MR(Q) – SMC(Q) = 0 • Profit-maximizing monopoly will equate MR to SMC to determine its optimal level of output • Profit-maximizing output Q* corresponds to where MR =SMC • Illustrated in Figure 12.2 • Firm will produce Q* units of output and, given market demand curve QD, it can sell all of this output at p* • p* corresponds to level of output Q* that consumers are willing and able to purchase

  8. Figure 12.2 Price and output determination for a monopoly

  9. Profit Maximization • SMC curve for a monopoly determines profit-maximizing price and output • However, in contrast to perfect competition, SMC curve above SAVC is not monopoly’s short-run supply curve • In Figure 12.2, if SMC curve for a monopoly is a supply curve, at a price of p* • Firm would be willing and able to supply Q'units of output • Although firm is able to supply Q'at p*, it is unwilling to supply it • Profit-maximizing output is Q* • Firm can sell all output at p* • Cannot determine a monopoly’s short-run supply curve without restrictive assumptions • Note that same factors that shift a monopoly’s short-run supply curve also shift SMC curve in same direction

  10. Profit Maximization • In Figure 12.2, price p* is above SATC* for output level Q* • Indicates monopoly is earning a pure profit • Represented by shaded area SATC*p*AB • TR is represented by area 0p*AQ* • STC is represented by area 0(SATC*)BQ* • Difference is pure profit • As illustrated in Figure 12.3, in short run a monopoly can also earn only a normal profit • When p* = SATC* • Due to increased input prices or a decrease in demand for its output • In this case, TR* =STC*, area 0p*AQ*

  11. Figure 12.3 Short-run profit maximization for a monopoly earning a normal profit

  12. Profit Maximization • In short run, a monopoly can also operate at a loss if demand falls or costs increase • Illustrated in Figure 12.4 • Losses represented by shaded area p*(SATC*)BA • As long as price is above SAVC a monopoly will continue to operate in short run • Monopoly will cover all of its STVC and have some revenue left over for paying a portion of its TFC • Monopoly minimizes its losses by operating • If price falls below SAVC, monopoly is unable to cover its STVC • Will minimize losses by shutting down • In summary, a monopoly can earn a pure profit, a normal profit, or can operate at a loss in short run • Firm’s level of profit is not an indicator of its degree of monopoly power • Percentage markup in price over marginal cost, (p -SMC )/p, is indicator of monopoly power

  13. Figure 12.4 Price and output determination for a monopoly operating at a loss

  14. Lerner Index • Regardless of its level of monopoly power • Firm only operates in elastic portion of demand curve • Given SMC > 0, a profit-maximizing firm will equate MR = SMC >0 • Using product rule of differentiation and recalling TR =pQ • Relationships of MR to price and to elasticity of market demand are • MR = dTR/dQ = p + (∂p/∂Q)Q • MR is equal to price plus adjustment factor

  15. Lerner Index • For each additional output sold price falls by ∂p/∂Q • Multiplying this by number of units sold results in adjustment to AR for determining MR • Factoring out price from right-hand side of MR =p + (∂p/∂Q)(Q) yields relationship between MR and elasticity of demand • MR =p[1 + (∂p/∂Q)(Q/p)] = p(1 + 1/D) • Where /D =(∂Q/∂p)(p/Q)], own-price elasticity of demand • For MR >0, (1 +1/D)> 0 • Which implies D < -1 (elastic) • If D > 1 (inelastic) • MR =dTR/dQ <0 • Decrease in Q will increase TR • Given dSTC/dQ >0, STC decreases with this decrease in Q • Yielding an increase in pure profit • Profit-maximizing firm can continue to reduce Q and increase profit within inelastic portion of demand curve • Firm will reduce output until it is in elastic portion of demand curve • Where MR =SMC • Table 12.1 summarizes relationships between demand elasticity and marginal revenue

  16. Table 12.1 Demand Elasticity and Marginal Revenue

  17. Lerner Index • At MR = SMC • MR = p(1 + 1/D) = SMC • Solving for p gives • p = SMC/(1 + 1/D) • Under perfect competition, a firm is facing a perfectly elastic demand curve • So 1/D =0, indicating condition of p =SMC for profit maximization • Instead, a monopoly charges a higher price • Since it only operates on elastic portion of demand curve • Then 0 <(1 +1/D) <1, so p >SMC • A measure of degree of monopoly power is percentage markup in price over marginal cost (p -SMC )/p • Specifically, given p(1 + 1/D) = SMC and solving for (p -SMC )/p yields Lerner Index (LI) • LI = (p – SMC)/p = -1/D • Lerner Index varies between 0 and 1 and measures percentage markup in price due to monopoly power • Relative difference in price and marginal cost is dependent on elasticity of demand

  18. Lerner Index • Under perfect competition, p =SMC, D = -, so LI= 0 • Firm is exercising zero monopoly power • If D = -1, then LI =1, indicating existence of monopoly power • At -1 ≥ D > -, corresponding to 0 <LI ≤1, a relative wedge between price and SMC exists • Magnitude of this wedge is determined by elasticity of demand • When demand curve becomes less elastic, wedge increases and LI approaches 1 • Wedge for a profit-maximizing firm without close substitutes will be large relative to a firm in a market with many competitors • Monopoly is concerned with effect high price has on consumption • When consumers react to a price increase by greatly reducing their demand • Monopoly will not charge highest price it can for its output • It will determine elasticity of demand for its output and calculate LI • Table 12.2 lists measurements of Lerner Index for steel and semiconductor industries

  19. Table 12.2 Measurements of the Lerner Index for the Steel and Semiconductor Industries

  20. Long-Run Equilibrium • Long-run equilibrium for a monopoly is illustrated in Figure 12.5 • SATC and LAC curves are tangent at firm’s profit-maximizing output level Q* • Where SMC =LMC =MR • At this equilibrium output and price (Q*, p*), firm is earning a normal profit • In long run, firm can earn only a normal profit • If it had been earning a pure profit in short run, when firm is sold in the long run • New owners will pay a higher price for firm than if it had been earning only a normal profit • Increases cost of operation • Results in upward shift of cost curves

  21. Figure 12.5 Long-run equilibrium for a monopoly firm

  22. Long-Run Equilibrium • Competition for purchasing firm will result in cost curves for new owners shifting up to point of zero pure profit (normal profit) • Market price for firm will increase until, in long run, all short-run pure profits are squeezed out • p =SATC =LAC • Even if firm is not sold, cost of production (in terms of implicit cost) will increase over time • In long run, a firm that earned a short-run pure profit will be worth more, say $100,000 • Thus, owners of firm have a higher implicit cost of production • Their opportunity cost for operating firm has increased because they could sell firm and receive this increase in price ($100,000) and invest it in another activity • Called opportunity cost of capital • If alternative activity had an annual rate of return of 10%, then firm’s implicit cost of production would be $10,000 higher • Short-run pure profit is converted into implicit cost • Alternatively, if firm had been operating at a loss in short run, firm will not be worth as much • Cost curves will shift downward, resulting in a long-run normal profit

  23. Long-Run Equilibrium • The worth of a monopoly based on its long-run pure-profit potential is called monopoly rents • Rent a possible entrant would be willing to pay for monopoly • Given positive monopoly rents, associated opportunity cost exists that result in only long-run normal profits • Without considering that cost adjusts to rents, it is possible to assume a monopoly will earn a long-run pure profit • This fact is particularly important in basic business decision-making • Since firms, even those with monopoly power, can only make a pure profit in short run • Owners of firms cannot continue their present activities and expect continued pure profits • If they want to continue to reap pure profit, must anticipate market trends • So as to sell their firms when conditions are right and be early entrants into markets where firms are earning short-run pure profits • However, many individuals or firms either lack this knowledge or are unwilling to act • Because they can maximize their utility by staying in a particular activity even if it means earning only a normal profit

More Related