1 / 32

A 1/n strategy and Markowitz' problem in continuous time

A 1/n strategy and Markowitz' problem in continuous time. Carl Lindberg 2006-10-06. Topics. Portfolio optimization and Markowitz’ problem’s problem A new stock price model The optimal strategy. I. Portfolio optimization and Markowitz’ problem’s problem.

meara
Télécharger la présentation

A 1/n strategy and Markowitz' problem in continuous time

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. A 1/n strategy and Markowitz' problem in continuous time Carl Lindberg 2006-10-06

  2. Topics • Portfolio optimization and Markowitz’ problem’s problem • A new stock price model • The optimal strategy

  3. I. Portfolio optimization and Markowitz’ problem’s problem • Introduction to portfolio optimization • Markowitz’ one-period problem • The Black-Scholes model • Markowitz’ problem in continuous time • The problem with estimating rates of return 

  4. 1. Introduction to portfolio optimization Natural idea: The investor wants to make money on the stock market • Specify stochastic model for stock prices • Fit model to data • Choose optimality criterion • Calculate optimal trading strategy

  5. 2. Markowitz’ one-period problem Stock return model Correlated normal variables One-period Investor trades in n stocks at time 0, holds position until time T. Trading strategies i: Proportion of initial wealth W(0) held in stock i 1-1-...-n: Proportion of W(0) held in bond Markowitz Find strategy =(1,..., n) that minimizes variance of terminal wealth W(T) while expected growth larger than predetermined constant

  6. 3. The Black-Scholes model independent Stock prices: volatilities Brownian motions • Black-Scholes is the standard model in finance: • Mathematically tractable: Stocks are geometric Brownian motions • Theoretically convenient: Market arbitrage free and complete • Fits data reasonably well • Parameters can in principle be estimated using normal statistical theory

  7. 4. Markowitz’ problem in continuous time Stock price model Black-Scholes model Continuous time Investor can trade in all n stocks at all times Trading strategies i(t): Proportion of wealth W(t) held in stock i at time t 1-1(t)-...-n(t): Proportion of W(t) held in bond at time t Markowitz Find admissible strategy (t)=(1(t),..., n(t)) that minimizes variance of terminal wealth W(T) while expected growth larger than predetermined constant: Progressively measurable and bounded

  8. 5. The problem with estimating rates of return  • Portfolio optimization has not received the same attention from the financial industry as option pricing theory • The predominant explanation is that the rates of return are very hard to estimate accurately • This gives extremely unstable portfolio weights when we apply the optimal strategies with parameters estimated from data with standard statistical methods

  9. 5. The problem with estimating rates of return  • Assume yearly returns for a stock are i.i.d. N(,),  = 0.20 • A 95% confidence interval for  is [Ŷ-1.96/√n, Ŷ+1.96/√n], where n is the number of yearly observations DATA FOR n=6147 YEARS IS NEEDED TO GET AN INTERVAL OF WIDTH 0.01!!! WE NEED MORE THAN NAÏVE STATISTICS (A common approach in the industry is to use linear models with some suitable predictors)

  10. II. A new stock price model • The new model • Equal company risk premiums • Covariance and volatility • Examples

  11. 1. The new model Black-Scholes parameterized as continuous time n-index Arbitrage Pricing Theory model with equal risk premiums: Same for all j ”Index”

  12. 2. Equal company risk premiums • One interpretation: Stocks are governed by n independent factors (indexes), each associated with a specific underlying company • Since we have no additional information on any company, the risk premium - r should be the same for all of them • Equal risk premiums gives coherence between the rates of return. This is not obtained by estimating the rates of return for each stock individually

  13. 3. Covariance and volatility • Classical Mathematical Finance: Volatility matrix  only used to model dependence between stocks • We can do more: A covariance matrix does not give a unique volatility matrix • Our model: Volatility matrix  decides rates of return, too • The investor can incorporate her views on specific stocks in the market model: She can choose a volatility matrix which implies relations between the rates of returns that she believes to hold

  14. 4. Examples: Cholesky decomposition • Assume that the investor has specified ranks for the stock risk premiums (SRP) for the n stocks: The stock with the lowest SRP is assigned rank 1, the second lowest rank 2, and so on.

  15. 4. Examples: Cholesky decomposition • Cholesky decomposition of the covariance matrix sorted by ranks gives a volatility matrix with clear tendency of assigning low SRP to stocks with low ranks • A stock with high rank is affected by some factors that do not influence stocks with lower rank. This makes the stock ”more diversified”, hence it is likely to have higher SRP

  16. 5. Examples: Matrix square root • Condition: All n companies are (approximately) equally important to each other • Assumption: Stock i depends as much on what happens to corporation j, as stock j depends on what happens to corporation i • Consequence: The volatility matrix should be symmetric • A symmetric volatility matrix is obtained by applying the matrix square root to the covariance matrix

  17. 5. Examples: Other alternatives • Any volatility matrix with a specified covariance matrix can be written as the Cholesky decomposition multiplied by an orthogonal matrix • Sparse volatility matrix • Assume conditional independence between different stocks given some factors, verify with statistical analysis • Use to assign ranks to groups of stocks, similarly to Cholesky decomposition

  18. III. The optimal strategy • Main goals • The 1/n strategy • An explicit solution * to Markowitz’ problem in continuous time • The 1/n strategy in factors • Advantages • Increasing the number of stocks • Applying the strategy * to data

  19. 1. Main goals • Goal I: Optimal strategies that are robust to misspecification of model parameters • Goal II: Investors can specify their unique market views through the optimal strategy without having to decide on exact numbers for the individual rates of return

  20. 2. The 1/n strategy • The investor puts 1/n of her wealth in each of n available assets • Advantage: No estimation of rates of return • Disadvantages: • Ignores dependence between stocks: Dependence can be estimated well We should use it • Not very low risk: Few factors determine much of dependence between stocks 1/n not really diversified

  21. 3. An explicit solution to Markowitz’ problem in continuous time We assume our new model Markowitz: Wealth: for the processes Progressively measurable and bounded Functions of 

  22. 3. An explicit solution to Markowitz’ problem in continuous time But the optimal strategy * must be constant, deterministic, and equal for every stock j This implies that the variance subject to the growth constraint is minimized by

  23. 3. An explicit solution to Markowitz’ problem in continuous time Hence, for sufficiently wide bounds on the admissible strategies the optimal strategy * solves for all t

  24. 3. An explicit solution to Markowitz’ problem in continuous time Optimal wealth process: Equality in law

  25. 4. The 1/n strategy in factors The strategy * • Prescribes that the investor should hold 1/n of her wealth in each factor/Brownian motion. The optimal strategy * is in this sense the most diversified strategy of all • Gives the optimal expected wealth of all portfolios with the same variance* is efficient

  26. 5. Advantages • We can expect stability of the portfolio weights when we use the optimal strategy * with parameters estimated from data. The reason is that the strategy * is based on estimates of the volatility matrix • The investor need not supply explicit estimates of rates of return to apply the optimal strategies. This is due to the natural coherence assumption that all corporations have the same company risk premiums

  27. 5. Advantages • The optimal strategy * can be applied without estimating values for the risk premium or choosing the required expected return : The investor’s views are obtained implicitly by the fraction of her wealth that she chooses to invest in the stock market. This choice corresponds also to the investor's risk-aversion • No utility function has to be selected. This is often required in classical optimal portfolio theory • The investor may still play a part….

  28. 6. Increasing the number of stocks • The figures show that the higher expected return the investor requires, the more she will have to risk. Nonetheless, the risk will still tend to zero as the number of stocks n increases. • Left: Distributions of optimal wealth at time T=1 for different n with parameters w=1, λ=0.1, μ=0.2, and r=0.03 • Right: Distributions of optimal wealth at time T=1 for different n with parameters w=1, λ=0.3, μ=0.2, and r=0.03 —n=200 — n=100 — n=50 — n=25 —n=200 — n=100 — n=50 — n=25

  29. 7. Applying the strategy * to data • 48 value weighted industry portfolios consisting of each stock at NYSE, AMEX, and NASDAQ • Data from 1963-07-01 to 2005-12-30. The covariance matrix is estimated with five years of data, and it is updated each month. The optimal strategy * is applied out-of-sample • We assume that the industry portfolios are approximately equally important to each other: We apply the matrix square root to the covariance matrix to get the volatility matrix

  30. 7. Applying the strategy * to data Normal distributions estimated from returns: Blue:The wealth process for the strategy*with 1-1-...-n=0 Red:The wealth process for the 1/N strategy Green: Industry portfolio with smallest volatility Magenta: Industry portfolio with largest volatility

  31. 7. Applying the strategy * to data Portfolio processes: Blue thick line:The wealth process for the strategy* with 1-1-...-n=0 Red thick line:The wealth process for the 1/N strategy Green thick line: The industry portfolio with smallest volatility Magenta thick line: The industry portfolio with largest volatility Colored thin lines: Individual industry portfolios

  32. 7. Applying the strategy * to data Sharpe ratios: Blue horizontal line:The wealth process for the strategy* with 1-1-...-n=0 Red horizontal line:The wealth process for the 1/N strategy Blue stars: Individual industry portfolios Memmel’s corrected Jobson & Korkie test of the hypothesis of equal Sharpe ratios between the wealth processes for the strategies * and  = 1/N gets a p-value of <<0.0001

More Related