1 / 30

THE CONSUMPTION FUNCTION

THE CONSUMPTION FUNCTION. Looking at Aggregate Demand (closed economy) Ep = C + Ip + G Assuming G is exogenous, this leads to enquiring into determinants of Consumption and Investment Consumption is of particular interest (multipliers, etc) Previously we have:

minna
Télécharger la présentation

THE CONSUMPTION FUNCTION

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. THE CONSUMPTION FUNCTION • Looking at Aggregate Demand (closed economy) • Ep = C + Ip + G • Assuming G is exogenous, this leads to enquiring into determinants of Consumption and Investment • Consumption is of particular interest (multipliers, etc) • Previously we have: • C = (1 - s)Y (0  s < 1) • or, C = C(Y - T) • We need to model the behaviour of C

  2. EARLY FORMULATION: KEYNES (1936) • Keynes (1936) made three main assertions: • C = C(Y), (not r) • 0  MPC  1, (where MPC is dC/dY) • APC falls as Y increases (APC is C/Y) • Taken together these imply a Consumption Function of the form: C = A + bY • where A and b are positive constants • APC = A/Y + b • MPC = b • and A/Y must fall as Y increases

  3. GRAPH OF THE BASIC CONSUMPTION FUNCTION • As Y increases, C/Y falls: also dC/dY  C/Y C 45O C = A + bY dC/dY = b A 0 Y

  4. EARLY EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE • Keynes hadn’t have much statistical evidence on consumption • Early estimates in the 1940s for the USA and elsewhere were conflicting. • Short-medium term annual data (1929-45) • C = A + bY; A 0; b  0.7 • Long-term data (1869-1945) • C = bY: A  0, b  0.9 • Which is “right”? • We need a proper model to answer this.

  5. LONG AND MEDUIM RUN EVIDENCE ON CONSUMPTION • 1929-45: C = A + bY • 1869-45; C = b*Y C 45O b* 0.9 C = b* Y C = A + bY b 0.7 0 Y

  6. MODELS OF AGGREGATE CONSUMPTION • Basic Intertemporal Choice model (Fisher) • The Life-Cycle theory of Consumption (Modigliani, etc) • The Permanent Income theory of Consumption (Friedman)

  7. INTERTEMPORAL CHOICE • Generally we require: PV(C)  or  PV(Y) • i.e. C1 + C2  (1+r)  or  Y1 + Y2 (1+r) • or  Ci  (1+r)i  or   Yi  (1+r)i • Households maximize Utility over expected lifetime • i.e. Max: U = U (C1, ..., Ci , ... , Cn) • s.t.  Ci  (1+r)i  or   Yi  (1+r)i(i : 1  n)

  8. INTERTEMPORAL CHOICE Indifference Curves represent U = U(C1 , C2 ) C2 C1 0

  9. INTERTEMPORAL CHOICE Endowment at E: OB = PV(Y) = y1 + y2  (1 + r) Slope of AB is  (1 + r) Y2 A . E y2 y1 Y1 0 B

  10. INTERTEMPORAL CHOICE Why is slope AB = - (1 + r) ? Suppose (present) savings increase by €100 i.e. C1 = - 100 This allows an increase in C2 of 100(1 + r) i.e. C2 = +100 (1 + r) Slope AB = C2  C1 = 100 (1 + r)/ - 100 = - (1 + r)

  11. A CHANGE IN r An increase in r: AB pivots at E  CD Y2 C A . E y2 y1 Y1 0 D B

  12. OPTIMAL C Saving is (oy1- oc*1) : future dis-saving is (oc*2 - oy2) Y2 A c*2 c* . y2 E 0 c*1 y1 B Y1

  13. CHANGES IN Y AND C Y2 increases: E’  E”, AB  CD, c’1  c”1 Y2 C A . E” . E’ 0 c’1 c”1 B D Y1

  14. A INCREASE IN r : SAVER Income effect 1 3; Substitution effect 3  2 Y2 C F A 2 3 1 . y2 E 0 y1 Y1 c31 c21 D B G c11

  15. A INCREASE IN r : BORROWER Inc. effect 1  2; Sub. effect 2  3 Y2 C A . F E 3 1 2 0 Y1 y1 c31 c11 c21 D G B

  16. IMPERFECT CAPITAL MARKETS Borrowing rate (EB) > lending rate (AE) C2 A . Y2 E 0 Y1 B C1

  17. CREDIT (BORROWING) CONSTRAINT . C2 I” Constraint: ADB I’ A Consumer cannot borrow more than Y1B E Y2 D 0 Y1 B C1

  18. THE LIFE-CYCLE HYPOTHESIS • Income shows a marked life-cycle variation • It is low in the early years, reaches a peak in late middle age and declines, especially on retirement • Smoothing consumption over a lifetime is a rational strategy (diminishing MUy) • This implies C/Y will vary during the lifetime of an individual

  19. THE LIFE-CYCLE HYPOTHESIS . C2 E’: low Y1/Y2  high C1/Y1 E”: high Y1/Y2  low C1/Y1 A E’ . C2* . E” C1 B 0 Y1’ C1* Y1”

  20. THE LIFE-CYCLE HYPOTHESIS Y, C and W over the life-cycle Y, C Ct Yt Age 18 65 +W Wt Age W

  21. THE LIFE-CYCLE MODEL • Let retirement age = 65; life expectancy = 75 • Years to retirement = R (= 65 – present age) • Expected life = T (= 75 – present age) • Assuming no pension, no discounting: • CT = W + RY is the lifetime constraint • i.e. C = (W + RY)/T • and C = (1/T)W + (R/T)Y • or C = W + Y ( = 1/T;  = R/T)

  22. THE LIFE-CYCLE MODEL • C = W + Y • MPC =  C Y =  • APC = C Y =  (W  Y) +  • clearly MPC < APC • for a “typical” individual, age 35 • R=30, T = 40 •  = 1/T  0.03;  (MPC) = RT  0.75 • APC = [0.03 (W  Y) + 0.75] > MPC

  23. THE LIFE-CYCLE MODEL • Saving and Consumption behaviour may depend on population age-structure • Does Social Security displace personal savings? • What is the effect of Medicare (USA) or Medical Cards for over 70s (IRL) on Savings? • Savings and Uncertainty: • “rational” behaviour: run down wealth to zero • individual circumstances unpredictable (care needs) • individual life expectancy unpredictable • on average even selfish people will die with W > 0

  24. THE PERMANENT INCOME HYPOTHESIS • Cp = kYp (0  k  1 ) • Y = Yp+ Ytr • C = Cp + Ctr • Permanent income is the return to all wealth, human and non-human: • Yp = rW • which implies: Cp = rkW • NB: C is not related to Ytr i.e. dC dYtr = 0

  25. MEASURING PERMANENT INCOME AND CONSUMPTION (1) • Are Cpand Yp observable? • E(Ytr ) = 0 • E(Ctr ) = 0 • which imply that E(Y) = E(Yp ), etc. • However this is ex ante: ex post, actual measures may reveal more • (a) in a recession: Y < Yp :  Ytr < 0 • (b) in a boom: Y > Yp :  Ytr > 0

  26. MEASURING PERMANENT INCOME AND CONSUMPTION (2) • Cross-section measurements of C and Y C 45o Ci, Yi. . . . . Ci = A + bYi . . Cm . 0 Y Ym

  27. MEASURING PERMANENT INCOME AND CONSUMPTION (3) • Where Yj > Ym, Ytr > 0 and Yj > Ypj C 45o Cp =kYp Cj Ci = A + bYi Cm Ytrj 0 Y Yj Ym Ypj

  28. MEASURING PERMANENT INCOME AND CONSUMPTION (4) • Aggregate: Ytr > 0 in boom, < 0 in recession • Measured C/Y should  be < in boom than in recession (Recent experience?) • Aggregate Ctr = 0: individual Ctr is > or < 0 • Average Ctr = 0 for all income groups • Measuring Yp: • Adaptive expectations: Yp = f(Yt, Y t - 1, ...Y t-n) • Rational expectations: only new information (shocks) change Yp • Consumption V Consumption Expenditure, which highlights the role of durables (Investment and saving rather than consumption

  29. MEASURING PERMANENT INCOME AND CONSUMPTION (5) • Also we may express the PYH as an error-correction model: • Ypt = Ypt-1 + j(Yt – Ypt-1) 0 < j < 1 • which with: Ct = Cpt = kYpt • gives: Ct = kYpt = kYpt-1 + kj(Yt – Ypt-1) • Re-arranging: Ct = (k – kj)Ypt-1 + kjYt • j  0 implies slow adaptation, j  1 implies rapid adaptation • assume k = 0.9, j = 0.3, so kj = 0.27 • then: Ct = (0.9 – 0.27)Ypt-1 + 0.27Yt or 0.63Ypt-1 + 0.27Yt • However this is not an explicitly forward-looking model. • Now suppose C = Cp = kYp, then Yp = 1/k(Cp) • Thus Ct = (0.63/k)Ct – 1 + 0.27Yt = 0.7Ct – 1 + 0.27Yt

  30. PERMANENT INCOME AND RECESSION • Y < Yp in short-run (mild) recession • Suppose there is a shock to the system (financial crisis) • Pwople expect a severe long-drawn-out recession: i.e. Yp falls, ie. E(Y) falls • It is possible that initiallyY > Yp • C (and Cp) will fall • If people anticipate a fall in Yp, then C/Y may fall • Current (mid-2009) situation: big fall in W, both the Permanent and Life-cycle theories predict that this will hit C (independently of current measured Y)

More Related