1 / 32

What is Benefit Cost Analysis About?

What is Benefit Cost Analysis About?. CONCEPTUALLY BCA IS SIMPLE. 1. Decide whose benefits and costs count (standing). 2. Select the portfolio of alternative projects. 3. Catalogue potential (physical) consequences and select measurement indicators.

stan
Télécharger la présentation

What is Benefit Cost Analysis About?

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. What is Benefit Cost Analysis About?

  2. CONCEPTUALLY BCA IS SIMPLE 1. Decide whose benefits and costs count (standing). 2. Select the portfolio of alternative projects. 3. Catalogue potential (physical) consequences and select measurement indicators. 4. Predict quantitative consequences over the life of the project. 5. Monetize (attach dollar values to) all consequences . 6. Discount for time to find present values. 7. Sum: Add up the benefits and costs. 8. Perform sensitivity analysis. 9. Recommend the alternative with the largest net benefit

  3. Choice Goods are scarce because desire for them far outstrips their availability from nature. Scarcity forces us to choose among available alternatives. The good/alternative not chosen/sacrificed is the true cost of the good/alternative chosen/gained. We are especially concerned about choices that have longer-term consequences

  4. Land (various degrees of fertility) Food (bread, milk, meat, eggs, vegetables, coffee, etc.) Natural (rivers, trees, minerals, Resources oceans, etc.) Clothing (shirts, pants, blouses, shoes, socks, coats, sweaters, etc.) Machines and other human-made physical resources Household (tables, chairs, rugs, beds, goods dressers, television sets, etc.) Space exploration Non-human animal resources Education Technology (physical and scientific “recipes” of history) Medical services Recreation Human (the knowledge, skill, resources and talent of individuals) Leisure time Entertainment Clean air Pleasant (trees, lakes, rivers, environment open spaces, etc.) Pleasant working conditions Scarcity and Choice Scarce Goods Limited Resources • History is a record of our struggle to transform available, but limited resources … into scarce goods – things that we would like to have.

  5. Assumptions • The use of scarce resources to produce a good is always costly Someone must give up something if we are to have more scarce goods. • Since information is scarce, uncertainty is a fact of life. • The value of a good is subjective and varies with individual preferences. Measured in terms of willingness and ability to pay and willingness and ability to sell • The highest valued alternative that must be sacrificed is the opportunity cost of the choice.

  6. Assumptions • Incentives matter As personal benefits (costs) from choosing an option increase, other things constant, a person will be more (less) likely to choose that option. • Economic reasoning focuses on the effects of marginalchanges in marginal costsand marginal benefits(utility) • In addition to their initial impact, economic events often generate secondary effects that may be felt only with the passage of time.

  7. OPTIMIZATION The basics The first thing we need to understand is the idea of optimization This just means finding the best alternative. The best alternative is called the optimal alternative, or the optimum • Optimizing may entail maximizing something good, or minimizing something bad.

  8. Benefits Benefits are anything that you consider good in a particular situation. That could be: • Money • Lives saved • Votes (if you are a politician) • Free time

  9. Let’s look at lives saved. An example of a benefit that you can see directly, but that is difficult to put in terms of money Modeling Healthcare Human Mortality Database

  10. The Situation 1: you’re the Minister of Health in a third-world country. Doctors Without Borders/Médecins Sans Frontières has offered your country 5 doctors. You must decide where to put them—in which district. The more doctors you put into a district, the more lives you will save in that district. Your objective is to save as many lives as possible.

  11. The Situation 2: • You have five doctors and two districts, Kinshasa and Ituri. • If we must use all the doctors together: we will put all five in Kinshasa or all five in Ituri. If we put them in Kinshasa we estimate they will save 925 lives; in Ituri, 920. • If our objective is to save as many lives as possible, to maximize lives saved, where should we put the doctors Kinshasa

  12. The rule is: choose the alternative with the biggest benefits. • Why can’t we save 925 lives in Kinshasa and 920 in Ituri? • Limited or scarce resources. This means is that if we want to get benefits in one place, we have to give up benefits someplace else. Benefits we have to give up are called costs: the cost of something is whatever other benefits we have to give up to get it.

  13. WHY? • But Doctors Without Borders/Médecins Sans Frontières is providing these doctors. So what are we giving up by using them in the Kinshasa district? • Answer: we are giving up lives in the Ituri district. • So we could say that putting the doctors in Kinshasa has benefits of 925 lives and costs of 920 lives.

  14. Rule 1a: Do something if its benefits are bigger than its costs. • We can write this more compactly as: Do something if B > C. • This is equivalent to saying: Do something if B - C > 0. • The term B - C, the difference between benefits and costs, is referred to as the net benefits of that activity. So we could say: Do something if its net benefits are positive.

  15. Marginal analysis • Now we can split up the doctors; we can send some to Kinshasa and some to Ituri. Our objective is the same as before: to save as many lives as possible. How many doctors should we send to each district? • To answer this question, we need information on the benefits of different numbers of doctors.

  16. Benefit figures for Kinshasa:

  17. There are two things about adding doctors in the Kinshasa district you should notice: • Benefits are increasing. More is better: the more doctors we have, the more lives we save.WHY? • Benefits are increasing at a decreasing rate WHY? [We can see this more easily if we calculate what is called the marginal benefit. This simply means the increase in total benefits from adding one more unit -- doctor]

  18. What is the marginal benefit of adding a doctor in Kinshasa? Here’s what that calculation looks like:

  19. Relationship between TB & MB Because the concepts of total and marginal are used a lot in applied welfare economics (BCA), it’s important to make sure that you understand the relation between the two. As long as marginal benefits are positive (i.e. greater than zero), total benefits will be increasing. Only when marginal benefits are negativewill total benefits start to decrease. How would we go from marginal benefit to total benefit? The total benefits are just the sum of the marginal benefits.

  20. What is the marginal benefit of adding a doctor in Ituri?

  21. Benefits and costs of doctors in Kinshasa

  22. Net Benefits of doctors in Kinshasa

  23. The general rule that we can see from this example is: • Rule 2a: To maximize net benefits, continue as long as marginal net benefits are positive (MNB>0). Or equivalently: Rule 2b: To maximize net benefits, continue as long as marginal benefits are greater than marginal costs (MB>MC).

  24. Review of what we did 1 • First, we had an objective. Here, our objective was to save as many lives as possible. • Then, we had to make some decisions about alternative ways of meeting those objectives. We are trying to optimize, which just means to do the best we can do with respect to our alternative. Each alternative had benefits associated with it, which are good things that we get from those alternatives. It also had costs, which are other good things that we have to give up in order to get these good things.

  25. Review of what we did 2 • What we want is for the net benefits, the benefits minus the costs, to be as big as possible. If we had a money-making business, say a restaurant, then benefits would be the money that comes in from our customers, and the costs would be the money that goes out for food and cooks and waitresses and rent and so on. Then net benefits would be the same thing as profit. But net benefits could be something else, like lives saved.

  26. Review of what we did 3 • When the question is how much of something to do, it’s helpful to look at marginal benefits and costs. Saying that we want net benefits to be as big as possible is the same as saying that we want to continue as long as marginal net benefitsare positive, which is to say, as long as marginal benefits are greater than marginal costs.

  27. Some bad rules • Benefit Cost Ratios Do something if B >C. Dividing both sides by C, we can see that this is equivalent to a rule that says: Do something if B/C > 1. But this does not mean that we should make the choice with the biggest benefit-cost ratio.

  28. Benefit Cost Ratios Examined

  29. Dealing with large numbers • When it’s inconvenient to think of benefits and costs as changing in many tiny little steps (although that is what’s actually happening), we can think of them as changing continuously. • Then we stop at the point where they are exactly zero, or where MB = MC. This is only an approximation. In most cases, there won’t be any point where marginal benefits and marginal costs are exactly equal. The more general rule is Rule 2, to continue as long as marginal net benefits are positive, or MB > MC.

  30. Get Real • How an economist would look at this issue: • Triage/sorting • Theory tells we should allocate some of our Drs. To both sites: 3/2 or 2/3 • Data aren’t really good enough to make choice • Why did I do it with numbers rather than theory? A Cost–Benefit Analysis of Cholera Vaccination Programs in Beira, Mozambique

  31. Review of what we did 1. Decide whose benefits and costs count (standing). 2. Select the portfolio of alternative projects. 3. Catalogue potential (physical) consequences and select measurement indicators. 4. Predict quantitative consequences over the life of the project. 5. Monetize (attach dollar values to) all consequences . 6. Discount for time to find present values. 7. Sum: Add up the benefits and costs. 8. Perform sensitivity analysis. 9. Recommend the alternative with the largest net benefit

  32. EndClass 1

More Related