1 / 43

Evan Blecher Health Economics Unit, University of Cape Town evan.blecher@uct.ac.za

The Economics of Tobacco Control in South Africa. Evan Blecher Health Economics Unit, University of Cape Town evan.blecher@uct.ac.za. Why regulate tobacco?. Negative externality Smokers Non-smokers Society Physical, financial & caring Health consequences Highly addictive

sternerj
Télécharger la présentation

Evan Blecher Health Economics Unit, University of Cape Town evan.blecher@uct.ac.za

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. The Economics of Tobacco Control in South Africa Evan Blecher Health Economics Unit, University of Cape Town evan.blecher@uct.ac.za

  2. Why regulate tobacco? • Negative externality • Smokers • Non-smokers • Society • Physical, financial & caring • Health consequences • Highly addictive • Highly dangerous • Most initiate use when they do not understand health consequences or addictiveness

  3. Why regulate tobacco? • Some statistics (Jha & Chaloupka, 2000) • 100 000 people smoke for the first time each day • Half of all smokers die from tobacco use • About half of these die in middle age • Globally 4 million die each year • Will be 10 million by 2030, 70% in the developing world • In the 20th century 100 million were killed • In the 21st century 1 billion will be killed • 2 jumbo jets of people die each day in the US from tobacco! • In SA 8.5% of all deaths are a result of smoking (MRC 2007) • Greater than alchohol & air pollution combined (MRC 2007)

  4. Tobacco control in South Africa • Pre 1993 • No tobacco control policy/strategy • 1993 Legislation • Banned smoking on public transport • Introduced warning labels on packaging and advertising • Coupled with consistent increases in excise taxes • Strongly opposed by tobacco industry

  5. Tobacco control in South Africa

  6. Tobacco control in South Africa • 1999 Legislation • Bans smoking in workplaces & other public places • Bans all advertising, promotion & sponsorship of tobacco • Bans sale of tobacco products to persons younger than 16 • Bans free distribution of products • Limits the maximum yield on tar, nicotine & other ingredients • What did the 1999 legislation do? • Public debate raised the awareness about tobacco risks • Transferred the property rights of clean air to non-smokers • Non-smokers now have the right to demand clean air

  7. Tobacco control in South Africa

  8. Tobacco control in South Africa • In 1999 South Africa was a global leader in tobacco control • Department of Health awarded the Luther Terry Award in 2000 by the American Cancer Society: “South Africa serves as a proven model for other low-income countries by showing what a determined and committed government can achieve for its people” • However, we are no longer at the cutting edge of tobacco control & in fact we do no meet the minimum requirements as set out in the Framework Convention on Tobacco Control to which we are a party • We still do not have a total ban on advertising (Article 13) • We still do not have a total ban on smoking in public places (Article 8) • Since South Africa is to host COP3 in November 2008: this is the time to act!

  9. Can increases in tax reduce government revenue?

  10. Prices & consumption

  11. Who gets what?

  12. Industry revenue: shouldn’t it have been falling?

  13. Input costs: raw tobacco

  14. Input costs: paper

  15. Employment: why has it been falling? Peak employment Peak consumption Merger

  16. Is tobacco control failing farmers? • The clear answer is no! • Agriculture on a whole has been in decline for nearly a century & specifically since 1994 • Tobacco Institute of South Africa (2004) lists the following challenges the tobacco farming community faced in 1994: • Free market introduced in SA • Tobacco in SA globalised • Farmers had to compete on world market • Manufacturers became multi-national players • World merchants entered SA • Growers declined from grater than 1000 to 630 • Mergers & acquisitions took place in primary and manufacturing industries • Very unsympathetic government: no assistance to farmers, very strict tobacco control legislation

  17. Illicit trade • Illicit trade is a legitimate concern, we can break it down into two distinct types: smuggling & counterfeiting • The industry argue that tax increases result in greater illicit trade, however they are equally responsible for the increases in the retail price of cigarettes • The industry also argue that higher taxes will reduce total tax revenue to government since it will reduce the sales of legal cigarettes • Warner (2000): “the tobacco industry itself appears to tolerate & actively encourage it, as indicated by recent court cases in which tobacco company executives have been found guilty of complicity in smuggling operations.” • Warner (2000): “The industry certainly benefits from increased sales associated with smuggling. Worldwide, nearly a third of legally identified exports find their way into the contraband market.”

  18. Illicit trade • What causes illicit trade? • Joossens & Raw (1998), Joossens (1999): • A countries’ general tolerance of corruption & the specific failure to police smuggling • Smuggling more prevalent in low income countries; no correlation between price & size of a country’s smuggling problem • Smuggling can be combated through better & complete record keeping, the use of tax stamps, greater penalties amongst other things • Warner (2000): “the threat of smuggling is systematically exaggerated by the tobacco industry to combat increased taxes that will discourage purchase of its product. The author is aware of no documented instances of tax revenues declining when tax rates were raised.”

  19. Restaurant restrictions • Two options: become entirely smoke free or separated areas • Original proposal was for a blanket ban • International Hotel & Restaurant Association Cape Town Survey predicted revenue would fall 32% • High compliance without police crackdowns despite the difficulty in enforcing • Federated Hospitality Association of South Africa indicated 85% non-compliance & sales down 37% • Saloojee & Ucko: “How can a law, that according to them (FEDHASA), is being widely ignored result in a loss of more than a third of sales?”

  20. Literature • Scollo et al (2003) • Studies that do not meet Siegel’s criteria generally find that legislation has had negative impacts in terms of financial performance; customer satisfaction & employment • Studies that meet criteria find little impact or positive impact • Scollo & Lal (2004) support this with updated data • Siegel’s (1992) methodological criteria • Control for economic conditions • Use of independent funding sources • Publication subject to peer review • Measurement of actual events rather than predicted outcomes or assessments

  21. A model for South Africa • Blecher (2006): South African Journal of Economics • Econometric modelling: real per capita revenue (proxied by VAT collections) is a function of • Real per capita income • Effect of the legislation • Efficiency of tax collection • Fixed effects panel model • Aggregate data → no sample selection problem • Provinces (nine) as cross sections • 1995 to 2003 • Small positive impact of policy

  22. Survey of restaurants • Van Walbeek, Blecher & Van Graan (2007): South African Medical Journal • Conducted by telephone during November 2004 & January 2005 • Sit down restaurants only, excluded takeaways & bars • Database included • 1431 restaurants • 1011 completed (70.6 %) • 230 established after the implementation (20.7 %) • Some problems • Sample is not random • Biased towards urban, tourist & business centres • Positives: perceptions corroborates VAT data

  23. Survey results • Changes to restaurant layout • Prior • 54% had specific smoking sections → 74% after • 75% had specific non-smoking sections → 97% after • A quarter have become entirely smoke free • Occupancy not significantly different • Compliance: 92% believe they are in compliance • In retrospect • 52% indicate they would not change the status quo • 23% entirely smoke free • 25% ignore

  24. Survey results • Financial Impact • Capital expenditure • Mean = R 67 000 ($ 9 571) • Median = R 25 000 ($ 3 571) • Malls & franchises spent more than independents • Linked to restaurant size • Revenues • Generally no significant impact • Franchises: generally positive • Independents: slightly negative • Interesting: greater capital expenditure resulted in greater positive impact (franchises)

  25. Change in revenues

  26. Acceptance by customers Non smokers Smokers

  27. International evidence

  28. International evidence

  29. International evidence

  30. International evidence

  31. Conclusion: smoke free • Legislation has had, if any, a small positive impact on restaurant revenues • No systematic harm done to restaurant industry • Smoking & non-smoking customers have accepted the policy well • Inline with international evidence • Implications • Supports the current legislation • Supports further legislation • Supports the implementation in other developing countries which do not yet have such policies

  32. Tobacco demand & advertising Two arguments: Anti tobacco lobby: Advertising increases consumption in the aggregate & influences initiation in vulnerable populations Tobacco industry: Advertising only influences brand market share, removes important health messages, reduces competition & forces industry to compete on price Question: In Zambia, BAT have an absolute monopoly, yet they continue to advertise? The literature provides no convincing empirical suggestions Time series: 9 no effect; 6 positive effect Cross sectional: 3 no effect; 5 positive effect (negative impact of ban)

  33. Tobacco demand & advertising Methodologically we should not attempt to measure the influence of advertising on consumption Saffer (2000): high level of aggregation leave little variation to correlate to changing consumption & the marginal product of advertising is very low since cigarettes are highly advertised (where allowed) We have a natural experiement taking place globally: more and more countries are restricting & banning advertising Saffer & Chaloupka (2000): comprehensive bans work in reducing consumption in OECD countries Blecher (2008): bans work in reducing consumption in developing countries, bans may even be more effective in developing countries relative to developed countries

  34. Advertising bans • Advertising of cigarettes is banned in South Africa • An exception is the point of sale • Yet the industry has pushed the boundaries of this ban & has stepped over the edge multiple times • The industry continue to advertise in magazines & at nightclubs • The point of sale has become the “final solution”

  35. Advertising bans • It is necessary for a total ban on all advertising in South Africa • This is the easiest & most efficient way to remove loopholes though which the industry operate • It will also further help reduce consumption & bring South Africa inline with its obligations to the FCTC • A final thought on advertising • Even if banning advertising does not reduce consumption it is the final avenue in which the tobacco industry can normalise tobacco • Banning advertising sends a clear message: tobacco is not normal

More Related