1 / 35

Econ 522 Economics of Law

Econ 522 Economics of Law. Dan Quint Fall 2009 Lecture 10. Logistics. Office hours between now and midterm: Me: Monday 1:30-3:30 Chao: today 1:00-3:00, Monday 10:00-1:30 Midterm #1 Tuesday, in class No contract law. Tuesday…. Why do we need contracts? What promises should be enforced?

alec
Télécharger la présentation

Econ 522 Economics of Law

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Econ 522Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2009 Lecture 10

  2. Logistics • Office hours between now and midterm: • Me: Monday 1:30-3:30 • Chao: today 1:00-3:00, Monday 10:00-1:30 • Midterm #1 Tuesday, in class • No contract law

  3. Tuesday… • Why do we need contracts? • What promises should be enforced? • Bargain Theory of Contracts • Efficiency • First purpose of contract law: enable cooperation • Second purpose of contract law: encourage efficient disclosure of information • Third purpose of contract law: secure optimal commitment to performance (efficient breach) • Fourth purpose of contract law: secure optimal reliance

  4. Efficient Breach

  5. Efficient Breach Efficiency: > Promisor’sCost Promisee’sBenefit Efficient to Breach  < Promisor’sCost Promisee’sBenefit Efficient to Perform  Self-Interest (incentives of promisor): > Promisor’sCost Promisor’s Liability Promisor will Breach  < Promisor’sCost Promisor’sLiability Promisor will Perform 

  6. Value to you = $500,000 Price = $350,000 Example of efficient breach • I build airplanes • You value one of my planes at $500,000 • You agree to buy one for $350,000, and pay up front • After you pay, price of materials goes up

  7. Value to you = $500,000 Price = $350,000 Example of efficient breach > Promisor’sCost Promisee’sBenefit Efficient to Breach  • Promisee’s benefit = $500,000 • If it costs me less than $500,000 to build plane, efficient to build it • If it costs me more than $500,000, efficient to breach

  8. Value to you = $500,000 Price = $350,000 Example of efficient breach > Promisor’sCost Promisor’sLiability Promisor will Breach  • Liability is just to return your money • If my costs rise to $400,000, performance is still efficient, but I’ll choose to breach • Liability is $1,000,000 • If costs rise to $700,000, performance is inefficient, but I’d rather perform than breach • Liability = promisee’s benefit ($500,000) • I’ll perform when performance is efficient, breach when breach is efficient

  9. Value to you = $500,000 Price = $350,000 But so what? Can’t we just“Coase” back to efficiency? • Liability is $350,000, my costs rise to $400,000 • I’ll breach original contract, but we can renegotiate to higher price • But I might try to do that even if my costs don’t go up… • Liability is $1,000,000, my costs rise to $700,000 • Rather than performing, I can offer you money to let me cancel contract • But my threat point is very low – you can demand a lot of money • If I realize that might happen, maybe I’m afraid to sign original contract • Expectation damages avoid these problems

  10. Another way to think about expectation damages: eliminating an externality • If I breach contract, I impose externality on you • You’re $500,000 worse off • If I have to pay you $500,000, then I internalize the externality • Now my action no longer affects your well-being • So I choose efficiently when deciding whether to perform or breach

  11. Reliance

  12. Next: Reliance • Reliance: investments you make to increase your benefit from performance • Increases my liability if I breach • If expectation damages include added benefit due to reliance, leads to more than efficient level of reliance • There’s some chance I’ll need to breach the contract • Your reliance investments increase my liability from breach, so they impose a negative externality • Activities which impose negative externality happen too much • Overreliance

  13. Reliance and Damages: example • Reliance increases your benefit from my promise • Airplane gives you benefit of $500,000 • Costs $75,000 to build a hangar • Airplane with hangar gives you benefit of $600,000 • Suppose price is $350,000, to be paid on delivery • Expectation damages restore you to well-being you expected to have from performance • Without a hangar, if I breach, I owe you $150,000 • If you build a hangar and I breach, do I owe you $250,000?

  14. Price of plane = $350,000 Value of plane = $500,000Cost of hangar = $75,000Value of plane + hangar = $600,000 Reliance and damages:example • Cost of building plane: maybe $250,000, maybe $700,000 • Clearly, you’ll choose to build the hangar • But, is that efficient? You build hangar You don’t You get I get You get I get Costsstay low 600 - 75 - 350 = 175 350 - 250 =100 500 - 350 =150 350 - 250 =100 Costsrise - 75 + 250 =175 -250 150 -150

  15. Price of plane = $350,000 Value of plane = $500,000Cost of hangar = $75,000Value of plane + hangar = $600,000 Reliance and damages:example • Let p be probability my costs go up • Combined expected payoffs if you rely: (1 – p) (175 + 100) + p (175 – 250) = 275 (1 – p) – 75 p = 275 – 350 p • Combined expected payoffs if you don’t rely: (1 – p) (150 + 100) + p (150 – 150) = 250 (1 – p) = 250 – 250 p • Which is bigger? 275 – 350 p > 250 – 250 p « 25 > 100 p « p < ¼ • So if p < ¼, reliance is efficient; if p > ¼, it’s not • But you’re going to rely either way!

  16. What do we learn? • When probability of breach is low, more reliance tends to be efficient • When probability of breach is high, less reliance tends to be efficient • If expectation damages include increased benefit from reliance, we sometimes get overreliance • (OTOH, if expectation damages exclude increased benefit from reliance, liability < benefit, so inefficient breach)

  17. So what do we do? • Cooter and Ulen: include only efficient reliance • Perfect expectation damages: restore promisee to level of well-being he would have gotten from performance if he had relied the efficient amount • So promisee rewarded for efficient reliance, not for overreliance

  18. So what do we do? • Cooter and Ulen: include only efficient reliance • Perfect expectation damages: restore promisee to level of well-being he would have gotten from performance if he had relied the efficient amount • So promisee rewarded for efficient reliance, not for overreliance • Actual courts: include only foreseeable reliance • That is, if promisor could reasonably expect promisee to rely that much

  19. Foreseeable reliance: Hadley v Baxendale • 1850s England • Hadley owned gristmill, mill shaft broke • Baxendale’s firm hired to transport shaft for repair • Baxendale shipped by boat instead of train, making it a week late • Hadley sued for the week’s lost profits • “The shipper assumed that Hadley, like most millers, kept a spare shaft. …Hadley did not inform him of the special urgency in getting the shaft repaired.” • Court listed several circumstances where broken shaft would not force mill to shut down • Ruled lost profits not foreseeable  Baxendale didn’t have to pay

  20. Default Rules

  21. Default rules • Gaps: risks or circumstances that aren’t specifically addressed in a contract • Default rules: rules applied by courts to fill gaps

  22. Default rules • Gaps: risks or circumstances that aren’t specifically addressed in a contract • Default rules: rules applied by courts to fill gaps • Writing something into a contract vs leaving a gap • Allocating a loss (ex post) • Versus allocating a risk (ex ante), before it becomes a loss

  23. What should default rules be? • Cooter and Ulen: use the rule parties would have wanted, if they had chosen to negotiate over this issue • This will be whatever rule is efficient

  24. What should default rules be? • Cooter and Ulen: use the rule parties would have wanted, if they had chosen to negotiate over this issue • This will be whatever rule is efficient • Fifth purpose of contract law is to minimize transaction costs of negotiating contracts by supplying efficient default rules • Do this by imputing the terms the parties would have chosen if they had addressed this contingency

  25. Default rules • Don’t want ambiguity in the law • So default rule can’t vary with every case • Majoritarian default rule: the terms that most parties would have agreed to • In cases where this rule is not efficient, parties can still override it in the contract • Court: figure out efficient allocation of risks, then (possibly) adjust prices to compensate

  26. Default rules • Example: probability ½, the cost of construction will increase by $2,000 • Construction company can hedge this risk for $400 • Family can’t do anything about it • Price goes up – who pays for it?

  27. Default rules • Example: probability ½, the cost of construction will increase by $2,000 • Construction company can hedge this risk for $400 • Family can’t do anything about it • Price goes up – who pays for it? • Construction company is efficient bearer of this risk • So efficient contract would allocate this risk to construction company • Should prices be adjusted to compensate?

  28. Default rules • Example: probability ½, the cost of construction will increase by $2,000 • Construction company can hedge this risk for $400 • Family can’t do anything about it • Price goes up – who pays for it? • Construction company is efficient bearer of this risk • So efficient contract would allocate this risk to constructioncompany • Should prices be adjusted to compensate?

  29. Default rules • So, Cooter and Ulen say: set the default rule that’s efficient in the majority of cases • Most contracts can leave this gap, save on transaction costs • In cases where this rule is inefficient, parties can contract around it

  30. Default rules: a different view • Ian Ayres and Robert Gertner, “Filling Gaps in Incomplete Contracts: An Economic Theory of Default Rules” • Sometimes better to make default rule something the parties would not have wanted • To give incentive to address an issue rather than leave a gap • Or to give one party incentive to disclose information • “Penalty default”

  31. Penalty defaults: Hadley v Baxendale • Baxendale (shipper) is only one who can influence when crankshaft is delivered; so he’s efficient bearer of risk • If default rule held Baxendale liable, Hadley has no need to tell him the shipment is urgent • So Hadley might hide this information, which is inefficient • Ayres and Gertner: Ruling in Hadley was a good one, not because it was efficient, but because it was inefficient… • …but in a way that created incentive for disclosing information

  32. Penalty defaults: other examples • Real estate brokers and “earnest money” • Broker knows more about real estate law • Default rule that seller keeps earnest money encourages broker to bring it up if it’s efficient to change this

  33. Penalty defaults: other examples • Real estate brokers and “earnest money” • Broker knows more about real estate law • Default rule that seller keeps earnest money encourages broker to bring it up if it’s efficient to change this • Courts will impute missing price of a good, but not quantity • Forces parties to explicitly contract on quantity, rather than leave it for court to decide

  34. When to use penalty defaults? • Look at why the parties left a gap in contract • Because of transaction costs  use efficient rule • For strategic reasons  penalty default may be more efficient • Similar logic in a Supreme Court dissent by Justice Scalia • Congress passed a RICO law without statute of limitations • Majority decided on 4 years – what they thought legislature would have chosen • Scalia proposed no statute of limitations; “unmoved by the fear that this… might prove repugnant to the genius of our law…” • “Indeed, it might even prompt Congress to enact a limitations period that it believes appropriate, a judgment far more within its competence than ours.”

  35. Default rules versus regulations • Default rules can be contracted around • Some rules cannot – immutable rules, or mandatory rules, or regulations • Fifth purpose of contract law is to minimize transaction costs of negotiating contracts by supplying efficient default rules and regulations. • Coase: if individuals are rational and there are no transaction costs, private negotiations lead to efficiency • So additional regulations would just get in the way • So regulations only make sense when people are not rational, or when there are transaction costs/market failures

More Related