1 / 34

Externalities

Externalities. Lecture 10 – academic year 2014/15 Introduction to Economics Fabio Landini. What do we do today?. The “ external ” effects of economic activities How do we internalize externalities?. The KYOTO Protocol – since 1997.

anika-combs
Télécharger la présentation

Externalities

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Externalities Lecture 10 – academic year 2014/15 Introduction to Economics Fabio Landini

  2. What do we do today? • The “external” effects of economic activities • How do we internalize externalities?

  3. The KYOTO Protocol – since 1997 • The Kyoto Protocol, signed in December 1997 at the UNFCCC COP3 (Conference Of Parties), represents the executive instruments of the Framework Convention • The countries that are subject to the emission constraint are 39 and they include the European countries (including the East countries), Japan, Russia, United States, Canada, Australia and New Zealand

  4. The KYOTO Protocol – since 1997 The European Directive 2003/87/CE“Emissions Trading” regulate the exchange of quotas for the emission of greenhouse gas. The final aim is to establish an European market for the emission quotas. During the first three years (2005-2007), the emissions of large combustion plants, such as oil refineries, plants for the production of ferrous metal, mineral goods (concrete, lime, etc.) and the plants for the production of paper and cartboard.

  5. Market efficiency: A brief recap • In a perfectly competitive market with no externalities the total welfare of the economic system is measured as the sum of consumer surplus and producer surplus. • “The invisible hand” (of the market) maximize the total benefit of society • Markets are usually good instruments to organize the economic activity • Sometimes, however: “market failures”

  6. Externalities: definition and effects When the transaction between a buyer and a seller has an effect on a third party, the effect on the latter is called externality. Whenever they do not take into account the “third party”, the equilibrium prices and quantities are not efficient. Therefore the externalities cause an inefficient allocation of resources, i.e. market failure.

  7. The effects of externalities on society In the presence of externalities: • Social welfare is not measured only by the welfare of consumers and producers, but also by the welfare of the third party (involuntary participant to the market). • The externalities can be negative or positive • However, ALL externalities are sources of market inefficiencies in the sense that the quantity exchanged ≠ optimal quantity.

  8. Negative externalities Costs on other individuals (consumers or producers) that are not directly involved in the market exchange. Example: smoke of cigarettes, cars’ exhaust gas

  9. Positive externalities Direct benefits obtained by individuals (consumers or producers) not directly involved in the market exchange. Example: Vaccines, restoration of a piece of Art, investment in new technologies.

  10. Externalities and market inefficiency • Negative externalities in production Qmarket> Qoptimum (socially desirable quantity) social costs > private costs • Positive externalities in production Qmarket< Qoptimum social costs < private costs

  11. Externalities and market inefficiency • Negative externalities in consumption Qmarket>Qoptimum (socially desirable quantity) Social benefit < private benefit • Positive externalities in consumption Qmarket<Qoptimum Social benefit > private benefit

  12. Social cost Cost of pollution Optimum QOPTIMUM Negative externalities in production Price of aluminium Supply (private cost) Equilibrium Demand (private value) 0 Quantity of aluminium QMARKET

  13. Value of technological diffusion Social cost Optimum QOPTIMUM Positive externalities in production Price of Robot Supply (private cost) Equilibrium Demand (private value) 0 QMARKET Quantity of Robot

  14. Optimum Social value QOPTIMUM Negative externalities in consumption Price of alcoholic drinks Supply (private cost) Equilibrium Demand (private value) Quantity of alcoholic drinks 0 QMARKET

  15. Optimum Social value QOPTIMUM Positive externalities in consumption Price of education Supply (private cost) Equilibrium Demand (private value) Quantity of education 0 QMARKET

  16. Positive externalities: the diffusion of knowledge A firm that starts a project (e.g., to produce industrial robot) could develop a new technology / generate an innovation in production techniques so as to improve the initial project. Such an improvement could benefit the firm but also the society as a whole, because such knowledge will accumulate and becomes part of the social knowledge stock. Technology diffusion: positive externality

  17. How to internalize externalities? The Government can provide subsidies to produce industrial robot. Example: subsidy for each robot that is produced. Increase of supply and therefore increase in the equilibrium quantity (previous graph). To obtain Qmarket= Qotpimum we need: subsidy = value of technology diffusion. Problem: how do we quantify this value?.

  18. Problem of industrial policy If the value of technological diffusion can be easily quantified, then the Government should design incentive (taxes, subsidies) that privilege high tech sectors as opposed to more traditional ones (INDUSTRAIL POLICY). If the value of technological diffusion is difficult to quantify, the risk is to end up helping sectors that have stronger lobbying power and not those with higher technological content. The best is to enforce PROPERTY RIGHTS through patents, which can then be licensed.

  19. How to obtain Qoptimum?1. Government intervention • Government can internalize the externalities by taxing the goods that causes negative externalities and by subsidizing those with positive externalities. • “To internalize an externality” means to alter market incentive with subsidies and taxes, so as to induce individuals to take adequately into account the external effects of their actions.

  20. Obtaining the optimal production If the externality is negative: internalization through a tax– the tax reduces the quantity that is exchanged in equilibrium until the social optimum obtains If the externality is positive: internalization through a subsidy– the subsidy increase the quantity that is exchanged in equilibrium until the social optimum obtains

  21. How to obtain Qoptimum?2. Private solution Public intervention is not always either necessary or efficacious to deal with externalities. Example of private solutions: • Ethical codes and social sanctions. • NGOs (in the “no-profit” sector). • Integration of different types of activities. • System of contracts (Coase’s theorem).

  22. Coase’s Theorem The model developed by the economist Ronald Coase is a well-known proposal to solve the externality problem without government intervention Coase’s Theorem: is the parties in a transaction can negotiate over the allocation of resources without costs, then the market can solve the externality problem.

  23. What does Coase’s Theorem mean? According to Coase externalities derive from the absence of well-defined property rights. If we assign exclusive property rights to some subjects the problem can be solved. Example: suppose we assign the exclusive rights to pollute to a single firm. The firm can decide to sell such rights, which will be then bought by the one who evaluate it the most.

  24. Consequences of Coase’s Theorem Private subjects can internalize the effects of externalities, negotiating among them. In this way, an efficient allocation of property rights can obtain. If transaction costs = 0, then the parties can always achieve the efficient allocation whatever the initial distribution of property rights is.

  25. Private solutions and public intervention Sometime private solutions do not work, because transaction costs are high (= cost necessary to achieve and enforce an agreement). This is more likely the higher the number of subjects involved in the transaction. This make it impossible to rely on private agreements.

  26. Externalities and public intervention When externalities are significant and private solutions are not viable, the Public Authority can react in one of two ways: • By creating laws and enforcement devices • By implementing market policies

  27. 1. Laws and enforcement devices Usually: bans and duty For instance: • No entry ban for non-Euro-3 cars • Vaccines • Heater can be switched on after 15/10

  28. 2. Market policies To align incentives and social optimum the Public Authority can decide to rely on “market policies”: • Regulation: determine a certain level of environmental pollution that is allowed. • Pigovian tax: create an incentive to reduce pollution. • Tradable permits: voluntary transfer of the rights to pollute from one firm to the other.

  29. Pigovian Tax Economists tend to prefer Pigovian Tax because it ensure a reduction of environmental pollution and lower social costs compared to regulation. Differently from regular taxation, it corrects the system of incentives and induce an efficient allocation of resources.

  30. Tradable permits They are used to fight environmental pollution. They allow the voluntary transfer of the rights to pollute from one firm to the other. In fact: a market for pollution rights is created. A firm that faces low cost to reduce her own pollution will prefer to sell her rights to pollute to a firm that faces high costs to reduce her own pollution.

  31. Supply of tradable permits Pigovian tax Price of pollution Price of pollution … together with demand it determins the price of pollution The Pigovian tax determines a price of pollution… P P Demand of tradable permits Demand of pollution rights 0 Q 0 Q Quantity of pollution Quantity of pollution Tradable permits define the quantity of pollution… . … together with demand it determines the quantity of polution (a) Pigovian Tax (b) Tradable permits

  32. Consumption tax on petrol Petrol is mong the most taxed goods (nearly 50% of final price in USA, nearly 75% in Italy). Often such taxes are conceived as (distortive) taxes on consumption (good with inelastic demand, see previous lectures….)

  33. Can consumption taxes on petrol (or cars) be conceived also as Pigovian taxes? In some respects the answer is YES. The tax is aimed at correcting externalities that are associated with the use of cars: • Traffic congestion. • Accidents (debate on SUV). • Street wearing out • Pollution. Question: aren’t there more appropriate tools to reduce pollution? A high price of petrol is paid by all citizens, even those that live in the country side and produce little pollution…

  34. Conclusion When the transaction between a buyer and a seller has effects on a third party, there is an externality. Negative (positive) externalities imply that the quantity that is exchanged in equilibrium is higher (lower) than the quantity that is socially desirable. Solutions to externalities can derive both from private parties and government intervention.

More Related