1 / 52

Electricity transmission pricing: getting the prices “good enough”?

Electricity transmission pricing: getting the prices “good enough”?. Richard Green Institute for Energy Research and Policy. Transmission pricing. Geographical differentiation in the wholesale market Prices for connecting to and using the transmission network. Six objectives.

breck
Télécharger la présentation

Electricity transmission pricing: getting the prices “good enough”?

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Electricity transmission pricing: getting the prices “good enough”? Richard Green Institute for Energy Research and Policy

  2. Transmission pricing • Geographical differentiation in the wholesale market • Prices for connecting to and using the transmission network

  3. Six objectives • Promote the efficient day‑to‑day operation of the bulk power market • Signal locational advantages for investment in generation and demand • Signal the need for investment in the transmission system

  4. Six objectives • Compensate the owners of existing transmission assets • Be simple and transparent • Be politically implementable Green (Utilities Policy, 1997)

  5. Three approaches • Ignore transmission issues • Ignore transmission issues, then bribe market participants to sort things out • Integrate transmission issues into your market design(s)

  6. Major power flows Source: UCTE

  7. Major power flows and congestion Congested 26-75% 76-99% 100% Source: UCTE

  8. PH Pricetrade PL Mpts If costs differ between areas P P GW GW Xpts

  9. Pricetrade If costs differ between areas P P GW GW Mpts Xpts

  10. Pricetrade If costs differ between areas and the lines are too thin… P P GW GW Mpts Xpts

  11. If costs differ between areas and the lines are too thin… P P T { GW GW Mpts Xpts

  12. Pricetrade If costs differ between areas and the lines are too thin… you could still ignore the problem P P GW GW Mpts Xpts but someone will want money to sort it out!

  13. Zones in the NEM • NEM runs nodal model and dispatches according to nodal conditions (prices) • Generators / loads grouped into regions • All generators in a region receive the regional reference price • Marginal cost at a reference node • No compensation for constrained running

  14. From a line to a network… • Electricity will flow along every path between two nodes • It “cannot” be steered • If one line fails, the flows instantly change • Overloading any line can be catastrophic

  15. (for example…)

  16. The impact of loop flows A B C

  17. The impact of loop flows A B C

  18. Nodal prices • Set price of power equal to marginal cost at each point (node) on the network • Marginal cost of generation (if variable) • MC of bringing in power from elsewhere • Centralised market uses the nodal prices • Bilateral trades which move power pay the difference in nodal prices

  19. Nodal trading • Price at A = 20, Price at B = 30 • I sell at A, I receive 20 • I sell at B, I receive 30 • I generate at A and sell at B, I receive the agreed bilateral price and pay (30 – 20) • I generate at B and sell at A, I receive the agreed bilateral price and pay (20 – 30) B A

  20. The impact of loop flows and constraints A B 6 MW at C needs 3 MW from A and 3 MW from B C

  21. Prices – constraint AB • Price at C = (Pa + Pb)/2 • 1 MW extra capacity allows 1.5 MW from A to replace 1.5 MW from B • Shadow cost of constraint = 1.5 (Pb – Pa) • If Pa = 10, Pb = 30 • Pc = 20, shadow cost = 30 • Pc = Pa + 1/3 shadow cost = Pb – 1/3 shadow cost

  22. A B C The impact of loop flows and constraints 3 MW at C needs –3 MW from A and 6 MW from B

  23. Prices – constraint AC • Price at C = 2Pb – Pa • 1 MW extra capacity allows 3 MW from A to replace 3 MW from B • Shadow cost of constraint = 3 (Pb – Pa) • If Pa = 10, Pb = 30 • Pc = 50, shadow cost = 60 • Pc = Pa + 2/3 Shadow cost = Pb + 1/3 Shadow cost

  24. A B C The impact of loop flows and constraints 3 MW at C needs 6 MW from A and –3 MW from B

  25. Prices – constraint CB • Price at C = 2 Pa – Pb • 1 MW extra capacity allows 3 MW from A to replace 3 MW from B • Shadow cost of constraint = 3 (Pb – Pa) • If Pa = 10, Pb = 30 • Pc = –10, shadow cost = 60 • Pc = Pa – 1/3 shadow cost = Pb – 2/3 shadow cost

  26. Summary

  27. Implications • Nodal prices can vary significantly • Over time • Over space • The first creates a need for hedging • The second makes it harder • The prices may be counter-intuitive

  28. How to hedge • Transmission Congestion Contract • Spatial contract for differences • Pays the holder the difference in nodal prices between two specified points (from A to B) • Price at B – Price at A • Perfect hedge if you generate that amount of power at A and sell it at B • Remember the real-time charge is (PB – PA)

  29. Who’d sell that hedge? • The spot market charges raise a surplus • Who gets it? • If the Transmission Congestion Contracts allocation is feasible, Hogan (1992) shows spot market surplus ≥ TCC payments • Organisation receiving the spot surplus can issue TCCs and find itself hedged!

  30. Inferior ways of hedging • Financial Transmission Rights (options) • Only pay out when value is positive • Payments may exceed spot revenues • Physical Transmission Rights • Limited by system capacity • If line limit on AB is 100, can only issue 100 • With TCCs, 100 BA “allows” an extra 100 AB • “Smeared” share of congestion revenues

  31. What if you get it wrong? • Operational difficulties • PJM’s first market • Economic operating mistakes • Investment mistakes • At present, we don’t know much about these

  32. How much does it cost to get it wrong? • Compare demand and operating patterns with different pricing rules • Model applied to England and Wales, 1996 data • Numbers are country- and time-specific • Approach is general

  33. The model • NGC system in 1996/97 • Thirteen zones (two pairs of NGC’s zones are combined, one zone split into two) • Iso-elastic demand in every zone • Generation in most £/MWh Gas, Coal, Nuclear Oil GW

  34. Transmission system model North A DC load flow model with losses (proportional to the square of flows) and constraints on the total flows across NGC’s system boundaries South-West

  35. Three pricing rules • One price for generation and for demand in each zone (optimal) • One price at each node for generation, but a common national price for demand • One national price for generation and one national price for demand (actual system) • Constraints are managed via payments for constrained-on and constrained-off running

  36. What is welfare? • NGC’s operating surplus • Kept the same under each of the rules • Generators’ operating surpluses • Energy revenues less variable fuel costs • Gas contracts assumed not to be variable • Consumer surplus • Area under their demand curve and above the price they actually pay

  37. Prices – winter peak

  38. Prices – summer trough

  39. Basic results

  40. Intuition for the results • Adjustments to generation for constraints have to happen, whatever the pricing rule • Here, these are in the same direction as the economic response to marginal losses • Cost differences at stations partially offset marginal transmission losses

  41. Market power • Sometimes a problem in this market • General incentive to raise prices • Particular incentive to raise prices in import-constrained area • Uniform pricing gives incentive to reduce prices in export-constrained area • Model two strategic generators plus fringe • Both firms change slope of bids (by region)

  42. Generators’ capacities North South-West

  43. Prices – winter peak

  44. Prices – summer trough

  45. Prices – zone 12

  46. Prices – zone 1

  47. Market power

  48. Conclusions of this study • Optimal pricing would create winners (northern consumers, southern generators) and losers (northern generators, southern consumers) • It would be less vulnerable to market power • Welfare gains of 1% of turnover are quite large as Harberger triangles go!

  49. Other transmission charges • Connection assets – local costs • Capacity-based use of system • Affect investment decision, not operating choices • Output-based use of system • Affect operating choices and might be used to offset consistent errors in the market rules • Contracts for constrained running

  50. Interactions between charges • Investing generators should consider both spot market and transmission charges • With the right spot signals, transmission charges should be uniform • Differentiated transmission charges needed if spot prices send inadequate signals • Using both would over-signal, reducing transmission costs, but raising generators’

More Related