1 / 56

Patent Data: An introduction Sant’Anna – Pisa (13.04.11)

Patent Data: An introduction Sant’Anna – Pisa (13.04.11). Bart Van Looy, Faculty of Business and Economics, K.U.Leuven INCENTIM - ECOOM (Centre for R&D Monitoring). Evolution of Patenting. Patents as an Incentive to Innovate (D. Guellec). History:

chinue
Télécharger la présentation

Patent Data: An introduction Sant’Anna – Pisa (13.04.11)

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Patent Data: An introduction Sant’Anna – Pisa (13.04.11) Bart Van Looy, Faculty of Business and Economics, K.U.Leuven INCENTIM - ECOOM (Centre for R&D Monitoring)

  2. Evolution of Patenting

  3. Patents as an Incentive to Innovate (D. Guellec) • History: • Nature is the creation of god(s): Romans, Catholic Church. Inventions are just discoveries by man of existing natural properties. • Locke (1690): a person who labours upon resources that are either unowned or ‘held in common’ has a natural property right to the fruits of his labour (natural right approach). • This view endorsed by some philosophers of the enlightenment inspired the first patent law in France (1791) stating that: ‘Every discovery of invention, in every type of industry , is the property of its creator; the law therefore guarantees him its full and entire enjoyment’

  4. Patents as an Incentive to Innovate (D. Guellec) • This view implies that patents are put in the realm of law and seen as a reward fairly deserved by the inventor, rather than an incentive serving society’s interest. • This argument was put forward by Locke regarding land and agriculture, but is application to intangible assets straightforward? • Locke himself noted: ‘… at least when there is enough, and as good left in common for others.’ • “Only god creates from scratch” • Everyone’s invention is based on accumulated knowledge, the sum of past inventions made by others… Granting ownership to the latest discovery implies also ownership of all previous knowledge leading to that invention? See the notion of ‘Creative commons’ nowadays (L. Lessig, Free Culture).

  5. “Each man is given a section of the hay to search. The man who finds the needle shows no more genius or no more ability than the others who are searching different portions of the haystack… To give patents for such routine experimentation on a vast scale is to use the patent law to reward capital investment and create monopolies for corporate organizers instead of men of inventive genius” Court decision by US Judge Arnold, 1941 (see also Schmookler, 1966). • “… ideas should freely spread from one to another over the globe, for the moral and mutual instruction of man, and improvement of his condition… (Jefferson, 1813)” • ‘Non rivalry’ character of knowledge.

  6. The utilitarian perspective: • Social institutions should be designed so as to maximize social welfare. • The core of the utilitarian argument for patents is that free competition will generate an under-optimal rate of inventions, due to the ‘public good’ characteristic of knowledge. • Hence it is in the interest of society to supplement free competition with special institutions in that field, patents being one of them. • From an utilitarian perspective, patents are viewed as incentives for further innovation. • Effectiveness of the patent system then depends on whether or not it stimulates future investement in knowledge creation (R&D) (for an example, see the current SW Patent debate).

  7. Economy of knowledge : • Marginal cost of reproducing knowledge is nearly 0. So investments in invention become sunk costs. • Re-inventing an existing piece of knowledge is a ‘waste’ (from a system perspective) • An existing piece of knowledge can be beneficial to others than the inventor without incurring the cost of invention and without depriving the inventor of the use: ‘positive’ spillover. Social returns > Individual returns. • If individual returns < social returns, but inventions depend on individual investments, overall investments will be lower than the desired level for the system as a whole. • A competitive market in this situation would make things worse as the inventing party will try to recuperate initial investments, while – free-riding – competitors will not incur these costs: initial investments in (uncertain) R&D will not be undertaken by rational decision makers. (see also D. Foray (2004) The economics of knowledge, MIT Press)

  8. Patents as an Incentive to Innovate (D. Guellec) • In fact, the market mechanism would not only lead to under-investment in research in general, but also possibly to excessive investments in particular areas. In the absence of legal protection, companies would keep their inventions secret, making it necessary for others to invest in duplication. • One solution for government is to sponsor inventors or inventions, and to put them later on in the public domain (scientific model?) • The alternative solution is to ‘privatize’ knowledge – to make it an excludable good, hence create intellectual property rights, like patent systems in place in Europe/US/OECD/….

  9. Patents as an Incentive to Innovate (D. Guellec) Current patent systems: • By granting exclusive rights, society is also generating costs, as these rights hamper the access to existing inventions, at least temporary (reduction of positive spill overs). • In addition, by granting temporary monopolies, ‘dead weight’ losses are being created (see p.79). • So the utilitarian view has at its core a tradeoff between benefits (incentives to invent) and costs (reduced diffusion, temporary loss of consumer surplus). • Temporary nature of monopoly and obligation to disclose are from this perspective crucial.

  10. What is a patent? (wikipedia.org) • A modern patent provides the right to exclude others from making, using, selling, offering for sale, or importing the patented invention for the term of the patent. A patent is, in effect, a limited property right that the government offers to inventors in exchange for their agreement to share the details of their inventions with the public. • In order to obtain a patent, an applicant must provide a written description of his or her invention in sufficient detail for a person skilled in the art to make and use the invention. This written description is provided in what is known as the patent specification, which often is accompanied by figures that show how the invention is made and how it operates. • In addition, at the end of the specification, the applicant must provide the patent office with one or more claims that distinctly point out what the applicant regards as his or her invention. A claim, unlike the body of the specification, is not a detailed description of the invention, but a succinct series of words designed to provide the public with notice of precisely what the patent owner has a right to exclude others from making, using, or selling.

  11. What is a patent? Certain areas are excluded (within certain patent systems) (1) European patents shall be granted for any inventions which are susceptible of industrial application, which are new and which involve an inventive step. (2) The following in particular shall not be regarded as inventions within the meaning of paragraph 1: (a) discoveries, scientific theories and mathematical methods; (b) aesthetic creations; (c) schemes, rules and methods for performing mental acts, playing games or doing business, and programs for computers; (d) presentations of information. EP Convention, 1973.

  12. PATENTABLE INVENTIONS ALL INVENTIONS PATENT APPLICATIONS INNOVATIONS Innovation relevant patent applications Innovation- relevant inventions Patent without patent applications application without Non-patented economic inventions without applications economic application Bringing knowledge into the production function equation Understanding the boundaries and the limits of the patent process: inventions >< innovations Patent prerequisites: - novelty - inventive step - application

  13. Other References Internet-based customer referral system Abstract Disclosed is an Internet-based referral system that enables individuals and other business entities ("associates") to market products, in return for a commission, that are sold from a merchant's Web site. The system includes automated registration software that runs on the merchant's Web site to allow entities to register as associates. Following registration, the associate sets up a Web site (or other information dissemination system) to distribute hypertextual catalog documents that includes marketing information (product reviews, recommendations, etc.) about selected products of the merchant. In association with each such product, the catalog document includes a hypertextual "referral link" that allows a user ("customer") to link to the merchant's site and purchase the product. When a customer selects a referral link, the customer's computer transmits unique IDs of the selected product and of the associate to the merchant's site, allowing the merchant to identify the product and the referring associate. If the customer subsequently purchases the product from the merchant's site, a commission is automatically credited to an account of the referring associate. The merchant site also implements an electronic shopping cart that allows the customer to select products from multiple different Web sites, and then perform a single "check out" from the merchant's site. References Cited [Referenced By] U.S. Patent Documents Primary Examiner: Voeltz; Emanuel Todd Assistant Examiner: Kalinowski; Alexander Attorney, Agent or Firm: Knobbe, Martens Olson & Bear, LLP

  14. Other references

  15. Applications (research): • Inventors (academic) • Fields (Biotech Regions – Emerging fields – Current work for EC DG Research) • Firms (Entry behaviour/Exploration – Role of relatedness/coherence – Ambidexterity)… • Innovation Systems (Role of universities/spill-overs between academia & industry…) • However, before we can discuss applications, data ‘enhancements’ might be/are crucial to address first

  16. Overview Role as a methodological expert for Eurostat (2008-2010, continued 2011-2013), member of Patstat Taskforce. • Sector Allocation • Regional Allocation • Name Harmonizing

  17. Patstat • http://documents.epo.org/projects/babylon/eponet.nsf/0/15E2334DC50BE0AEC125767F005A91ED/$File/PATSTAT_flyer_en.pdf • http://www.epo.org/searching/subscription/raw/product-14-24.html

  18. Sector Allocation

  19. Sector Allocation

  20. Regional Allocation

  21. Regional Allocation

  22. Regional Allocation

  23. 1. Original method: Intro • First version developed 2005-2006 for EPO and USPTO patentees (all 270,635 applicants in EPO ESPACE ACCESS 1978-2004 and all 223,665 assignees in USPTO Bibliographic raw data 1991-2003) • Name harmonization (spelling variations, typos, addition of legal form and variants), not legal entity harmonization (business units, departments, name changes, joint-ventures, subsidiaries, mergers and acquisitions) • Content driven (case based) and rule based • Conservative (maximum precision, recall of secondary importance) • Transparent and modular methodology and implementation • Labor-intensive development but automated implementation • Only using information available in the database

  24. Harmonizing < > Consolidation • Construct long list of (subsidiary) names(annual reports, company websites, SEC, Dun&Bradstreet, …) • Construct keyword list based on long list and use these keywords to search in patent database • Validate results of keyword search

  25. Consolidation: Example

  26. 1. Patent portfolios and patentee name linking: Results • Average number of EPO applications with assignee names different from the current parent name (and variations): 19.5% • Strong differences amongst and within sectors:Engineering & machinary: 32.0%Electronics & electical: 23.6%Chemicals: 18.6%Pharmaceuticals & biotech: 15.2%IT hardware: 10.5% • On average 1 day of work for large companies

  27. 1. Original method: Summary • Character cleaning • Punctuation cleaning • Legal form indication treatment • Common company word removal • Spelling variation harmonization • Condensing • Umlaut harmonization

  28. Precision (<> Recall)

  29. 1. Original Method: • Reduction of unique patentee names from 443,722 to 365,866 (17.6%) • Reduction of number of patentees having only 1 patent from 281,760 to 219,821 (22%) • Average patent increase of 33.1% for matched names (absolute maximum for ‘IBM’ from 28,469 to 41,173, relative maximum for ‘H. G. Weber & company’ with 86%) • Top 10 patentees unchanged except for IBM (from third to first place) • Extensive validation on small subset of 35 patentees: 100% precision and 99.6% recall • All details available in EUROSTAT working paper: Magerman, T., Van Looy, B. & Song, X. (2006) Data Production Methods for Harmonized Patent Indicators: Patentee Name Harmonization. EUROSTAT Working Paper and Studies, Luxemburg

  30. 2. Current update: Extension and revision • Extensive update and review based on all patentees present in PATSTAT, edition April 2009 (about 11 million patentee names) • Increase in rules from 1,300 to about 4,000 • Complete new implementation of the toolbox was crucial (relational database system not performant enough – 0.1 millisecond per rule evaluation would still result in 50 days computer processing for all 4,000 rules on 11 million names). Traditional procedural implementation in JAVA runs the complete batch in 2 days.

  31. 2. Current update: Results • About 11 million patentee records in PATSTAT edition April 2009 (9,104,503 unique names) • Of the final 7536191 unique harmonized names, 946134(12.6%) names match more than one original name, ranging from 2 to 393 • On average 37% increase in patent count • Different impact amongst patent offices • Underestimation of impact because of presence of individuals

  32. 2. Current update: Precision validation • Precision validation on 4 random samples (2 times 250 harmonized names, 2 times 1,000 harmonized names - 6,927 original names in total) • No errors in small samples, 2 respectively 3 errors in harmonized names in bigger samples, resulting in 16 erroneous linked original patentee names • 99.8% precision

  33. 2. Current update: Precision errors • 'YING QUN‘ • 'YING, QUN‘ -> 'YINGQUN COMPANY‘ • 'YINGQUN CO., LTD.’ • 'PAUL, S.’ -> ‘PAUL, S.’ • 'PAULS LTD'

  34. 2. Current update: Recall validation Overall, recall > 90 % (of patent volume <> names) Extension towards all patent offices creates lower levels of recall (<> EPO/USPTO/EPO) Some ‘simple’ harmonizing activities remain complex to automate (without jeopardizing precision elsewhere) Introduction of ‘manual’ check for top patentees (500) (under development)

  35. 3. Practical issues: Status • Beta version ready of both method (rule file) and toolbox • Data file ready (new harmonized PATSTAT PERSON table for all 11,000,000 patentees of April 2009 edition), including PERSON_ID for easy linking to PATSTAT database • Ability to process all patentees of new releases of PATSTAT within 6 – 10 days • Highly adaptive method capable of dealing with corrections and extension without the need to recode or recompile the toolbox • Very promising preliminary precision rates (99.8%) • Recall validation reveals issues to resolve

  36. 3. Practical issues: Distribution and feedback • Ready for launch? • Preliminary distribution as a pilot to gather reactions, corrections and updates? • How to distribute? Part of PATSTAT? Seperate download? • Highly adaptive method: gather and incorporate incremental improvements ? (e.g. case based information like ‘BASF’ = ‘Badische Anilin- und Soda-Fabrik’) • Set up community? • Practical arrangements for new updates of PATSTAT?

  37. Characterization of non-patent references Source: Callaert, J., Van Looy, B., Verbeek, A., Debackere, K. and B. Thijs. (2006), Traces of Prior Art: An analysis of non- patent references found in patent documents. Scientometrics, 69(1), 3-20. Non-patent references (NPRs) in patent documents: used as indicator of science-technology links However: not all NPRs can be considered as ‘scientific’:

  38. Characterization of non-patent references • Targetall non-patent references in PATSTAT (~ 11,4 mio NPRs) • Objectiveto identify the (scientific) nature of non-patent references • Methodclassification rules based on keywords and exact matching procedures (near complete accuracy), complemented with supervised machine learning approach (near complete coverage)

  39. Characterization of non-patent references • Supervised machine learning approach: • teaching the computer to recognize patterns, based on an input sample of already classified data (> 25000 manually classified NPRs, called the “training set”) • this pattern recognition is then generalized to classify other data in an automated way (based on linear discriminant analysis)

  40. Characterization of non-patent references • Complementarity from dual methodological approach • Coverage • Accuracy

More Related