290 likes | 452 Vues
Effects of Inter-agent Communications on the Collective. Emergence of robust leadership structure and market efficiency. Zoltán Toroczkai. (Complex Systems Group, LANL). Marian Anghel (CNLS-LANL). György Korniss (Rensellaer Pol. Inst.). Kevin Bassler (U. Houston).
E N D
Effects of Inter-agent Communications on the Collective Emergence of robust leadership structure and market efficiency Zoltán Toroczkai (Complex Systems Group, LANL) Marian Anghel (CNLS-LANL) György Korniss (Rensellaer Pol. Inst.) Kevin Bassler (U. Houston)
Resource limitations lead in human, and most biological populations to competitive dynamics. The more severe the limitations, the more fierce the competition. Amid competitive conditions certain agents may have better venues or strategies to reach the resources, which puts them into a distinguished class of the “few”, or elites. Elites form a minority group. In spite of the minority character, the elites can considerably shape the structure of the whole society: since they are the most successful (in the given situation), the rest of the agents will tend to follow (imitate, interact with) the elites creating a social structure of leadership in the agent society. Definition: a leader is an agent that has at least one follower at that moment. The influence of a leader is measured by the number of followers it has. Leaders can be following other leaders or themselves. The non-leaders are coined “followers”.
Agent-system (society): -- a set of discrete, autonomous entities (individuals, agents, players) with a certain degree of intelligence, adaptability, and flexibility in the choice of their actions in response to external stimulus, or to follow personal goals (maximize or minimize a set of utility functions). -- there is no (or very little) centralized control -- there is a globally available world utility function which rates the past performance of the collective (world history function). -- the choice of response function of an agent couples to: the world utility function information gathered from neighboring agents on the social network, via Reinforcement Learning. [D.H. Wolpert, K. Tumer (2000): COIN]
The El Farol bar problem [W. B Arthur(1994)] A B …
A binary (computer friendly) version of the El Farol bar problem: The Minority Game (MG) [Challet and Zhang (1997)] A = “0” (bar ok, go to the bar) B = “1” (bar crowded, stay home) latest bit l {0,1,..,2m-1} World utility(history): (011..101) m bits S(i)1(l) S(i)2(l) (Strategies)(i) = (Scores)(i) = C (i)(k), k = 1,2,..,S. S(i)S(l) (Prediction) (i) =
A(t) t
Attendance time-series for the MG: World Utility Function: Agents cooperate if they manage to produce fluctuations below (N1/2)/2 (RCG).
Somemacroscopicproperties • Predictability (Phase transition) • Unused strategies -freezing • Persistence– Anti-persistence
The Minority Game on Networks (MGoN) Agents communicate among themselves. Social network: 2 components: 1) Aquintance (substrate) network: G (non-directed, less dynamic) 2) Action network: A (directed and dynamic) G A G A
Communication types (more bounded rationality): Minority rule Majority rule (not rational) (not rational) Critic’s rule: an agent listens to the OPINION/PREDICTION of all neighboring agents on G, scores them (self included) based on their past predictions,and ACTS on the best score. (more rational, uses reinforcement learning) (Links)(i) = (Scores)(i) = F (i)(j), j= 1,2,..,K. i (Prediction) (i) =
Social Networks How do they look like? 1. Degree distribution (number of acquitances a person has) : - it is strongly peaked around a mean degree: there is a recurring cost in terms of time and effort for maintaining a connection. This is a resource as well a cognitive limitation. [MEJ Newman, D. Watts, S. Strogatz, PNAS, 99, 2566, (2002) ].
Data: EpiSims Census data, from Portland Oregon, 1.6 mill. people [H. Guclu, Z. Toroczkai, … (2002)]
[MEJ Newman, D. Watts, S. Strogatz, PNAS, 99, 2566, (2002) ].
2.“Small world-ness”: it takes only a small number of acquaintances to reach almost anyone in the world: D log (N), where D is the number of steps, N is the number of vertices (people) in the graf. Milgram’s experiment: [J. Travers, S. Milgram, Sociometry 32, 425 (1969).] D 6-7. [D.J. Watts et. al. , Science, 296, 1302 (2002)
- search in social networks is effective because of the high dimensionality of the social space (provides shortcuts). 3. Clustering or transitivity: A Very likely! B C ki=5 Clustering distribution: ni=3 Ci=0.3 i Average clustering coefficient:
Location networks: People move around. Two locations are connected by an edge if a person went from A to B. A B Not very likely C - expect much less clustering
[H. Guclu, Z. T., … (2002)] Power law tail, exponent: –2.4
Network types: *1) Regular network with node degree k: *2) Erdös-Rényi Random networks with link probability p. • shows the small-world effect: 3) Small-world networks generated from regular networks (Watts, Strogatz, Newman) . 4) Scale-free networks (Albert-Barabási). (irrelevant here)
Critic’s Rule on a regular network Uniform aggregation does not pay off!
Network Effects: Possibility for Improved Market Efficiency • A networked, low trait diversity system • is more effective as a collective • than a sophisticated group! • Can we find/evolve networks/strategies • that achieve almost perfect volatility • given a group and their strategies • (or the social network on the group)? Improved market efficiency
Macroscopic Properties – Network Effects • Reduced persistence: • The network is very efficient at • removing any arbitrage opportunities! • Reduced predictability and phase • separation: followers and leaders • Unused links – freezing on action network and persistence
Emergence of scale-free leadership structure: m=6 • Robust leadership hierarchy • RCG on the ER network produces the scale-free • backbone of the leadership structure • The influence is evenly distributed • among all levels of the leadership • hierarchy.
The followers (“sheep”) make up most of the population (over 90%) and their number scales linearly with the total number of agents. • Structural un-evenness appears in the leadership structure for low trait diversity.
N=101, S=2 • Leadership position: Symmetric-Asymmetric phase transition M=3 M=2 • In low m regime, where trait diversity is low (as in a dictatorship) leaders leave longer! M=6 M=8
SOME CONCLUSIONS: • We modeled the inter-agent communications across a social network which forms the skeleton for information passing in a competitive game with bounded rationality. • The game evolves the active network by coupling via reinforcement learning • on the agent-level. The game is influenced by the inter-agent communications. • A robust leadership structure emerges naturally. The structure is scale-free • and evenly distributed for large trait diversities. The more even is the distri- • bution the more de-correlated are the agent’s choices in the strategy space. • The leaders’ position is more persistent/stable the lower the trait diversity. • Networking can lead to a more efficient collective for low-trait diversity • agents. It is detrimental for large trait diversities.