1 / 36

Full employment or a 'natural' rate of unemployment (NAIRU)? by Dr Alfred Kleinknecht

Full employment or a 'natural' rate of unemployment (NAIRU)? by Dr Alfred Kleinknecht Emeritus Professor of Economics Fellow of WSI, Wirtschafts- und Sozialwissenschaftliches Institut, Hans Bӧckler Stiftung, Düsseldorf alfred-kleinknecht@boeckler.de. Historical Background:

hao
Télécharger la présentation

Full employment or a 'natural' rate of unemployment (NAIRU)? by Dr Alfred Kleinknecht

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Full employment or a 'natural' rate of unemployment (NAIRU)? by Dr Alfred Kleinknecht Emeritus Professor of Economics Fellow of WSI, Wirtschafts- und Sozialwissenschaftliches Institut, Hans Bӧckler Stiftung, Düsseldorf alfred-kleinknecht@boeckler.de

  2. Historical Background: After the Great Crisis (1929-1941) … • A 'Golden Age of Capitalism' (1946- ca. 1973): • Unprecedented economic growth • Low unemployment • Low inflation • Fairly stable financial markets • Broad consensus: • Manchester capitalism is passé • Economic stability through fiscal and monetary policy • Solid regulation of financial markets • A decent security net The Age of Keynes!

  3. After the 'Golden Age' (1946-73) there is a turning point around 1975-1985: • Slowdown of economic growth … • … which cannot be reversed by fiscal stimulation • Oil price shock and 'Stagflation' (stagnation + inflation) • 'Dutch Disease' → plant closures and mass unemployment • Growing government debt burden • Keynesian macro-models make tough forecasting errors All this was a fruitful breeding ground for an anti-Keynesian counter-revolution from the right: Supply-side economics!

  4. Supply-side economics (1): • Passive economic policy: no more fiscal stimulation; only monetary policy for fighting inflation • Striving for greater income inequality: 'Performance must pay!' • Deregulation of labor markets: easier firing! • Cutting back on social security ('it makes people passive!') • Retreat of government: deregulation, liberalization, privatization; Hayek (Nobel Prize 1974): 'Minimal State'! • Deregulation of financial markets: more room for financial innovation! • Markets are never wrong … and government is at the roots of every problem!

  5. Supply-side economics (2): NAIRU = Non-Accelerating Inflation Rate of Unemployment . Theory of 'Natural Unemployment'→ You need a sufficiently large rate of unemployment in order to discipline labour and prevent inflation through high wage claims Estimated rates of NAIRU ('natural' unemployment rates): Netherlands 4.5%; most other countries: 5-7% If unemployment is below the NAIRU level, there is a risk of wage-price inflation! → the ECB will intervene by raising interest rates → restore ‘sufficient’ unemployment → strong competition for scarce jobs assures modest wage claims … Frame: The Euro has to be a hard and reliable currency!

  6. Supply-side economics works (at least in one point):Greater inequality … Share in National Income in the US: Of the richest 10%: • 33% in 1976 • 50% in 2007 … and of the richest 1%: • 8.9% in 1976 • 23.5% in 2007 Source: Atkinson, Piketty and Saez (2011)

  7. US: Average income of the bottom 90% and of the top 1%, 1933-2006 Keynesiaanse periode Supply-side politics Krediet

  8. US: Domestic debt as a percentage of GDP (1950-2007)"Household" = Consumer and mortgage debt"Business" = Total non-financial business sector debt"Financial" = Total financial sector debt"Public" = total public sector debt (local and federal) Hefboom financieringen! Source: US Federal Reserve Zeepbel met huizenprijzen → hogere hypotheken voor consumptie

  9. The labour market for professors in full employment equilibrium How could we get long-lasting (mass) unemployment among professors? As professors become cheaper, universities buy more of them (as with apples!) S = Supply of professors As wages rise, more people offer themselves as professors Equilibrium wage W e D= Demand for professors Market clearing equilibrium quantity

  10. Professors get unemployed as their wages are too high! One way to full employment: Follow the green arrows! Aggressive trade unions raise wages S = Supply of professors Market clearing wage D = Demand for professors Q Universities demand fewer professors Supply of professors is too high Unemployed professors

  11. The dominant neo-classical view: High European unemployment is due to labour market rigidities: the price of labour is downwardly rigid and cannot adapt to economic shocks Key policy targets: Lower minimum wages Lower social benefits More tailor-made wage contracts (de-centralization of wage bargaining → allow for a more unequal income distribution!) Easier firing: change power relations on the shop floor Reduce the power of trade unions (= cartels that act against the real interest of labour!)

  12. LME countries: USA Canada Australia Ireland Great Britain New Zealand CME ('Old Europe'): Most continental European countries Japan 'Liberal Market Economies' (LME) versus 'Coordinated Market Economies' (CME) according to Hall & Soskice (2001)

  13. LME (Anglo-Saxon): Easy hiring and firing Shorter stay in same firm Modest unemployment benefits Weak trade unions Wage bargaining more de-centralized: income distribution more unequal CME ('Old Europe'): Protection against firing Longer stay in same firm Generous unemployment benefits Strong trade unions Wage bargaining more centralized: more income equality Labor market institutions in LME versus CME Strong protection of labor Strong protection of investors

  14. Labor market institutions in LME versus CME:Is there a difference in economic performance? (incomes? job creation? Productivity growth? GDP growth?)Looking at some key variables …

  15. Anglo-Saxon labour market institutions lead to modest wage growth… Development of real wages, 1960 = 100

  16. Differences in real wage growth make no difference for GDP growth

  17. … but it does make a difference for labour productivity growth

  18. Development of labor hours 1960-2004 (1960 = 100) 200 180 160 140 120 100 80 60 40 20 0 1960 1975 1990 2011 1963 1966 1969 1972 1978 1981 1984 1987 1993 1996 1999 2002 2005 2008 Anglo-Saxons create more jobs … ! … and for labour input Anglo-Saxon countries: US, UK, Canada, New Zealand, Australia EU-12 excl. Luxemburg … or they have to work longer for the same GDP …

  19. Is there a causal link from wage growth to labour productivity growth? Traditional argument: • Labour productivity growth → wage growth (end of story) Alternative view: • There is also a link: wage growth → labour productivity growth (estimated coefficients: 0.39 ~ 0.49) Source: R. Vergeer & A. Kleinknecht (2011): 'The impact of labor market deregulation on productivity: A panel data analysis of 19 OECD countries (1960-2004)', Journal of Post-Keynesian Economics, Vol. 33 (2): 371-407. N.B. Evidence at macro-level is meanwhile confirmed by a series of firm-level studies

  20. Reasons for feedback from wages to labour productivity growth: Neoclassical theory: • Factor substitution • Vintage effect • 'Induced' technical change Evolutionary theory: • 'Creative destruction' (Rehn-Meidner theorem)

  21. Theoretical arguments about the impact of flexible labour on labour productivity (1): • Difficult and expensive firing of redundant personnel frustrates labour-saving process innovations (Bassanini & Ernst, 2002; Scarpetta & Tressel, 2004) • With easier firing, shifting labour from old and declining industries to innovative activities is easier (Nickell & Layard, 1999) Counter arguments: • Difficult firing gives incentives for training thus increasing functional flexibility; • People on the shop floor possess much of the (tacit) knowledge required for process innovations. People threatened by easy firing have incentives to hide knowledge relevant to labour-saving process innovations (Lorenz, 1992, 1999)

  22. Theoretical arguments about the impact of flexible labour on labour productivity (2): • Easier firing enhances the inflow of 'fresh blood' (i.e. of people with novel ideas and networks) • Powerful labour may appropriate rents from innovation, thus reducing the incentive to take innovative risks (Malcom­son, 1997; Menezhes-Filho & Van Reenen, 2003; Metcalf 2002) ↕ • Counter argument: This holds primarily for (Anglo-Saxon) de-centralized wage bargaining and much less for (European) centralized bargaining

  23. Theoretical arguments about the impact of flexible labour on labour productivity (3): • The (latent) threat of easy firing reduces shirking (→ Counter argument: this is poor HRM policy!) • Firms can more easily replace weak people by better personnel (→ Counter argument: a fallacy of composition!)

  24. Theoretical arguments about the impact of flexible labour on labour productivity (4): Flexible 'hire & fire' reduces loyalty and commitment: • Greater chances that trade secrets and technological knowledge will leak to competitors, larger positive externalities leading to stronger under-investment in knowledge. • There is more need for monitoring and control. Anglo-Saxon countries have substantially larger management bureaucracies which is frustrating for creative people (Kleinknecht et al. 2006).

  25. Norway Spain Greece Sweden Italy Switzerland Belgium Ireland Germany Portugal Japan Denmark Finland Austria Netherlands U.K. Australia USA Canada 0 5 10 15 Managers as a percentage of the non-agrarian working population Share of managers in working population (19 OECD countries, 1984-1997) According to De Beer (2001), the Dutch figure increased from 2% to 6% during 1978-98

  26. Theoretical arguments about the impact of flexible labour on labour productivity (5): Given easier firing and higher labour turnover: Firms will reduce investments in manpower training as pay-back periods become shorter. Personnel have fewer incentives to invest in firm- specific knowledge (e.g. safety instructions) A larger personnel turnover weakens the 'historical memory' of organizations and the 'learning organization'. Easy firing of personnel will change power relations in firms. People will less easily criticize management decisions. Lack of critical feedback from the shop floor can favour problematic management practices.

  27. Theoretical arguments about the impact of flexible labour on labour productivity (6): Schumpeter I model (1912): 'Entrepreneurial model': new firm foundation (e.g. in ICT, biotechnology); inventor-entrepreneur ('Garage business'). Schumpeter II model (1942): 'Routinized innovation model': Professionalized R&D labs in large firms. Incremental innovations based on continuous accumulation of (tacit) knowledge with strong path dependencies Impression from trade statistics: Anglo-Saxon countries perform better in Schumpeter I regimes 'Old Europe' performs better in Schumpeter II regimes

  28. This table is inspired by: S. Breschi, F.Malerba & L. Orsenigo (2000): 'Technological regimes and Schumpeterian patterns of innovation', in: Economic Journal, Vol. 110: 288-410.

  29. Rounding up (1): Are flexible labour markets good for labour productivity growth? Evidence at macro and micro level: • Flexible labour relations and wage restraint lead a to lower growth of labour productivity and a more labour-intensive (less capital-intensive) growth path • Ironically, this resembles the factor-intensive growth pattern in Eastern Europe before 1989! • A low-productive and labour-intensive growth path is problematic with an ageing population in Europe!

  30. Rounding up (2): Can we create more jobs under an LME regime (with deregulated labour markets)? A likely scenario if the NAIRU doctrine remains dominant! Probably 'Yes': if you succeed to bring down labor productivity growth But note: According to the logic of a declining demand curve for labor, you have to create mainly lower-paid jobs i.e. create a larger group of 'working poor' Anglo-Saxon countries with deregulated labor markets have higher shares of working poor ('outsiders')

  31. Rounding up (3): Can we bring down unemployment under an 'Old Europe' regime? Probably 'No' (or at least doubtful) under protective 'Old Europe' labor market institutions … Why? High productivity growth! Law of Verdoorn → higher growth of GDP will trigger higher growth of GDP/working hour (= labor productivity)! N.B: In the past, Europe had long periods of high GDP growth in which input of working hours stagnated (or even slightly declined) → But full employment has been achieved through shorter working times … A desirable Green-Left scenario (?) … but undesirable from a NAIRU viewpoint!

  32. Development of labor hours 1960-2004 (1960 = 100) 200 180 160 140 120 100 80 60 40 20 0 1960 1975 1990 2011 1963 1966 1969 1972 1978 1981 1984 1987 1993 1996 1999 2002 2005 2008 Years Anglo-Saxon countries: US, UK, Canada, New Zealand, Australia EU-12 excl. Luxemburg

  33. Rounding up (4): Do Anglo-Saxon countries have lower unemployment rates? • Yes: Nickell, Nunziata & Ochel: 'Unemployment in the OECD: What do we know?', in: Economic Journal, Vol. 115 (2005): 1-27. • Doubts: According to our re-estimates*, their results are not robust! → It is doubtful whether the 'flexible' countries indeed have lower unemployment rates (in spite of their labour-intensive growth!) Why no lower unemployment rates? • Anglo-Saxon countries have generous immigration policies • In the aftermath of Reaganomics: Longer working hours • The role of the Central Bank (NAIRU!) *Source: Vergeer, R. & A. Kleinknecht (2012): 'Do flexible labor markets indeed reduce unemployment?' in Review of Social Eco­nomy, Vol. LXX (December): 451-467.

  34. Summarizing: What are the main differences between CME and LME? The two regimes do not differ with respect to: • Long run economic growth • Unemployment rates (although LMEs create more jobs) Where do they differ? • LME have lower rates of labour productivity growth (value added per labour hour); so they have to work more hours for the same GDP - in exchange they create more jobs • Income distribution in LME is more unequal (more working poor) • Innovation: • Old Europe does better in Schumpeter II industries • LME do better on Schumpeter I industries

  35. NAIRU = Non-Accelerating Inflation Rate of Unemployment Summarizing: The most important barrier to full employment: NAIRU theory The European Central Bank has the task of assuring a sufficiently high level of unemployment (in the name of fighting inflation) → prevent 'too much' solidarity by assuring strong competition for scarce jobs Handsome frame: The Euro should be a 'hard' and 'solid' (say: investor-friendly) currency!

More Related