1 / 25

Industrial Organization I

Industrial Organization I. Price discrimination. Classification. Direct Discrimination. Formally : Monopolist solves : Foc’s are: After some manipulation :. Direct Discrimination: Welfare. p. p 1. p 2.

hawa
Télécharger la présentation

Industrial Organization I

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Industrial Organization I Price discrimination

  2. Classification

  3. Direct Discrimination • Formally: • Monopolistsolves: • Foc’s are: • Aftersomemanipulation:

  4. Direct Discrimination: Welfare p p1 p2 • In some cases, price discrimination provides goods and services to groups that would not have access under uniform pricing: • Prescription drugs: developed vs. developing countries D1 + D2 MC p*2 D2 p*1 D1 q*1 q1 q*2 q2 Q* MR Q MR1 MR2

  5. Direct Discrimination: Welfare • Firm is better off (in the worst case the firm is as well off) • Consumers in low elasticity markets are worse off • Consumers in high elasticity markets are better off

  6. Direct Discrimination: Inter-related Demands • Direct (or group) price discrimination analysis also applies to “inter-related” demands: • Electricity (off peak v. peak) • Durable goods markets • Monday night movie discounts? Wing Tuesday?

  7. Indirect Discrimination • Consumers self-select • Firm knows about two (or more) consumer types • It is unfeasible (or illegal) to use direct discrimination (arbitrage will happen) • Again, two possible kinds of “packages” • Two-part tariff: e.g. $100 for a plan, and 10c/min after 1000 min • Take it or leave it offer: buy one get one 50% off.

  8. Indirect Discrimination • Packages must comply with 2 constraints: • Incentive compatibility: we want groups to select the package designed for them • Participation: consumers must purchase (i.e. the package designed for them gives them positive utility)

  9. Graphical Illustration: Two part tariff pC Residential Commercial pR • Assumption: MC=0 • With 2 prices (6 & 12), commercial has no incentive to choose $12 • Solution: 2 plans: a)12¢/min (“12 plan”), b)6 ¢/min (“6 plan”) + fixed fee (fixed # min) • Compatibility: CSC(12 plan)>=CSC(6 plan), commercial chooses “12 plan” • “6 Plan”: fixed fee? 9 minutes? 18 minutes? • Participation: Residential must choose “6 plan” (“12 plan” is never chosen) • CSR(6)>0: 135 – 108 = 27; you can actually do better. How? 24 36 81 12 DC 12* 135 144 108 DR 108 6* qR qC 12* 18 24 6* 9 12 18

  10. Implications of ID • Low demand consumer has marginal value that exceeds marginal cost (inefficiently small amount) • High demand consumer has marginal value equal to marginal cost (efficient quantity) • We will derive this result formally below (in a simple model)

  11. A simple model (take-it-or leave it) • Assumptions: • 2 consumers • Consumer 2 is high demand, consumer 1 is low demand: • Firm is a monopolist and sells to two consumers (quantities x1 and x2)

  12. A simple model • Utility is quasi-linear: • This simplifies to: Inverse demand

  13. A simple model • Firm sets package based on inverse dd • Consumer pays and gets units (take-it-or-leave-it package):

  14. A simple model • Participation constraints: • Incentive compatibility constraints (also “self-selection” constraints):

  15. A simple model • Rearranging: • Let’s show that in each pair of constraints, only one constraint can be binding Consumer 1 Constraints (A) (B) Consumer 2 Constraints (C) (D)

  16. A simple model • Let’s see if (C) can be binding [r2=u2(x2)] : • Since • It follows that: • Which contradicts (A)

  17. A simple model • Hence, (D) must be binding: • Now, let’s consider consumer 1’s constraints: • Suppose (B) is binding: • Plugging (E) in the last expression: (E)

  18. A simple model • Last expression can also be written as: • But this violates the assumption: • Hence, (A) must be binding

  19. A simple model • Under the assumptions made: • Low demand consumer is charged his maximum willingness to pay (i.e. derives zero utility) • High demand consumer is charged highest r2 that makes him indifferent between x2 and x1 (but derives positive utility)

  20. A simple model • Profit Maximization • Rearranging (F): (F)

  21. A simple model • This implies (just as in our graphical two-part tariff illustration above): • Low demand consumer has marginal value that exceeds marginal cost (inefficiently small amount) • High demand consumer has marginal value equal to marginal cost (efficient quantity) • More on this in homework 3

  22. Indirect Discrimination: Examples • Buy 1 at $50, get one at half price ($25) Consumer Surplus 50 Elastic demand 25 1 2

  23. Indirect Discrimination: Examples • Buy one, get one half price • Incentive compatible, participation constraint satisfied Consumer surplus 50 25 Inelastic demand 1 2

  24. Important Points • Uniform (aka linear) pricing within a segment can only be used for direct price discrimination (not for indirect PD) • For indirect discrimination to work, a non-linear scheme needs to be offered: (r,q) contract or a two-part tariff contract (A,p) • Two-part tariffs and packages can be used in all three price discrimination schemes

More Related