1 / 0

Lecture 3

Lecture 3. Price Theory. Market Power, Collusion, and Oligopoly Chapter 11. Acquiring Market Power. Mergers Horizontal integration Vertical integration Antitrust policies Predatory pricing Resale price maintenance (RPM). Mergers. Horizontal integration Produce same good merge

isla
Télécharger la présentation

Lecture 3

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Lecture 3
  2. Price Theory Market Power, Collusion, and Oligopoly Chapter 11
  3. Acquiring Market Power Mergers Horizontal integration Vertical integration Antitrust policies Predatory pricing Resale price maintenance (RPM)
  4. Mergers Horizontal integration Produce same good merge Ex. Dell, Gateway, and IBM Vertical integration Merge so produce inputs used to produce output Ex. Dell and Intel
  5. Horizontal Integration Reasons to merge Isolate economies of scale and capture monopoly power Competing welfare concerns Reducing costs and creating monopoly power Ex. Great American Merger Wave
  6. Welfare implications Consumers Can be good or bad for consumers Depends specifics of market structure Small firms Can be good for small firms not involved in the merger if the merging results in a higher product price. Can be bad if merging results in higher efficiency (ie, lower MC)
  7. Antitrust Policies Sherman Act of 1890 Clayton Act of 1914 Prevent mergers tend to reduce competition Controversy over antitrust criteria Economic efficiency US Supreme Court versus European antitrust position
  8. Vertical Integration Two monopolist merge Eliminate monopoly power Benefit consumers (why?) Increase total surplus after merger Other types of vertical integration Good or bad Depends specifics of market structure Shapes of demand and cost curves
  9. Predatory Pricing Damage rival firms Sets prices artificially low Skepticism about use in marketplace Difficult to define Unlikely to last long, if adopted, because of negative profit Competitors re-emerge once the PP is over The “prey” companies are not always vulnerable
  10. Resale Price Maintenance (RPM) Producer Set retail price and forbid any retailer to sell at discount Benefits according to the retail service argument: Wholesaler – better off (larger sale) Retailer – better off or unchanged Consumer – better off (CS is larger) Prices or service kept high if the value added by retailers is sufficiently large
  11. Resale Price Maintenance This retail service argument does not always hold. RPM is prohibited in the US and in Taiwan, however, RPM remains a common practice in Taiwan.
  12. Resale Price Maintenance Question: does the retail service argument apply to the issue of online bookstores (such as books.com.tw) and physical bookstores so gain your support for RPM in this case? News about bookstores: Subsidy for small bookstores Tax deduction for physical bookstrores
  13. Oligopoly An industry in which individual firms can influence market conditions. We begin with introducing three different models of oligopoly.
  14. Fixed Number of Firms Stackelbergmodel Cournot model Take rivals output as given Production level Bertrand model Take rivals prices as given MC and pricing move toward competition
  15. The first model is the Stackelberg model, for instance, IBM and its follower. It is a quantity setting game and 1 is the leader who chooses to produce y1 while after seeing that, the follower, 2 decides to produce y2. The total output of the market is therefore y1+y2 and the price is p(y1+y2). (sequential)
  16. Solving backwards, follower’s problem maxy2 p(y1+y2)y2-c2(y2). FOC: p(y1+y2)+p’(y1+y2)y2=c2’(y2). So basically, from FOC, we can derive the reaction function of 2. That is, given y1, there is an optimal level of y2. In the following we will work with the case where p(Y)=a-bY and c2(y2)=0 for all y2. 2=(a-b(y1+y2))y2=ay2-by1y2-by22 and FOC: a-by1-2by2=0 or y2=(a-by1)/2b (reaction function).
  17. Two points worth mentioning. When y1=a/b (1 has flooded the market), then y2=0. On the other hand, when y1=0, it is as if 2 is the monopolist, so y2=a/2b. Let us suppose c1(y1)=0 for all y1 and work out the leader’s problem: maxy1 p(y1+y2)y1-c1(y1). Now, we can plug in 2’s reaction curve. So 1=(a-b(y1+(a-by1)/2b))y1=(a-by1)y1/2. FOC: a/2-by1=0 So y1=a/2b.
  18. Plugging this into 2’s reaction curve, we get y2=(a-b(a/2b))/2b=a/4b. Show this graphically. Now turn to the Cournot model. Two firms simultaneously decide output levels. We look for the case where 1’s output is a best response to 2’s and vice versa 2’s is a best response to 1’s. Graphically, it is the intersection of the two reaction curves.
  19. Fig. 27.2
  20. Since y2=(a-by1)/2b and symmetrically y1=(a-by2)/2b, solving these two together, we get y1=y2=a/3b. Suppose the two quantity setting firms get together and attempt to set outputs so that their joint profit is maximized, i.e., they collude or form a cartel, what will the output levels be? Their problem becomes maxy1,y2 (a-b(y1+y2))(y1+y2). FOC: y1+y2=a/2b.
  21. Fig. 27.4
  22. Bertrand model It is a model of price competition between duopoly firms which results in each charging the price that would be charged under perfect competition, known as marginal cost pricing.
  23. Bertrand model Assumptions: There are at least two firms producing homogeneous products; Firms do not cooperate; Firms have the same marginal cost (MC); Marginal cost is constant; Demand is linear; Firms compete in price, and choose their respective prices simultaneously;
  24. Bertrand model There is strategic behavior by both firms: Both firms compete solely on price and then supply the quantity demanded; Consumers buy everything from the cheaper firm or half at each, if the price is equal. Competing in price means that firms can easily change the quantity they supply, but once they have chosen a certain price, it is very hard, if not impossible, to change it, for example bars or shops or other companies that publish non-negotiable prices.
  25. Bertrand model vscournot model Although both models have similar assumptions, both have very different implications. Bertrand predicts a duopoly is enough to push prices down to marginal cost level, that duopoly will result in perfect competition. Neither model is necessarily "better". If capacity and output can be easily changed, Bertrand is generally a better model of duopoly competition. Or, if output and capacity are difficult to adjust, then Cournot is generally a better model. Can you provide any example?
  26. Other market structures Many researchers are unsatisfied with these oligopoly models, as needed assumptions are to some extent unrealistic. Other models are developed: Contestable market Monopolistic competition Game
  27. Contestable Markets Firms enter and exit costlessly (This is the focus of this model) Airline market as a typical example Assume identical firms If AC curves cross industry demand in upward-sloping region Price, AC, MC all equal
  28. Contestable Markets Why is this model interesting? Realistic -- It describes markets served by a small number of firms, which are nevertheless characterized by competitive equilibria. The theory of contestable markets has been used to argue for weaker application of antitrust laws, as simply observing a monopoly market may not prove that a firm is exploiting its market power to control the price level.
  29. Monopolistic Competition Market where there are many similar but differentiated products. Similar products remain close substitutes. Thus, the demand curve facing an firm is downward sloping, but relatively flat (elastic). Entry is allowed in the long run.
  30. Monopolistic Competition Implications: Since we expect monopolistic competitors to face quite elastic demand curves, the deviation of output from the competitive level might not be too great. In the LR, profit is pressed to zero, but still not at the competitive level.
  31. Product Differentiation There are many ways to differentiate products so as to form a market close to monopolistic competition. Brand names Hiring an attractive girl to sell betel nuts or soy food Location
  32. Economics of Location Difference exaggerated or minimized Vendor location Final location Political parties – median voter theorem
  33. Hotelling model: consumers populate uniformly on a line and two firms have to choose a position. Consumers go to the store that is closest.
  34. Fig. 25.7
  35. Prisoner’s Dilemma – using game theory to analyze oligopoly Game with 2 players Commit crime Decide how to play game Choose best strategy Invisible hand does not hold true Repeated Prisoner’s Dilemma Tit-for-Tat
  36. Breakdown of Cartels Price initially set above MC Cheating promoted Competitive output level Analogous to Prisoner’s Dilemma Ex. NCAA Enforcers Government Monopoly retailer
  37. Regulations and market power Regulations increase market power for those who meet the standards. Some benefit and some others suffer from regulations. In the case of quality regulations, for example, people with lower income suffer more. (why?)
  38. Examples of Regulation Quantity Quality Information Prices Business practices
  39. Regulating quality Typical examples are regulations on drugs. (The U. S. Food and Drug Administration, FDA, for example) They can be good and bad: Good: poor quality drugs are harmful Bad: access to drugs is delayed Peltzman (1987) analyzes the effect of 1938 drug regulations and concludes that mandatory prescriptions were unlikely to save lives or lead to other health improvements! Peltzman (1973) finds that the Kefauver Amendments in 1968 (requiring drug producers to prove their drugs safe) have cost more lives than saved.
  40. Regulating information Typical examples are regulations on advertisements They can be good and bad: Good: advertisements increase costs unnecessarily Bad: advertisements increase competition then lower prices Benham (1972) investigates this question in the market for eyeglasses and found that the price of eyeglasses was higher by 25-100% in states where advertising was prohibited.
  41. A handsome application of theory of monopoly Article by Lin Chuan, former Treasurer in Taiwan, analyzing Taipowerand monopoly. Main argument: Rate-of-return regulation applied to a monopoly firm leads to over-investment. We have mentioned before that profit regulation (or zero profit regulation) applied to a monopoly firm leads to over production:
  42. A handsome application of theory of monopoly Averchand Johnson's (1962) work suggested that the profit-maximizing firm under rate-of-return regulation fails to minimize the cost of producing any observed level of output, that these productive inefficiencies might be large, and that the firm might even build up its rate base by selling competitive outputs at a price below marginal cost.
  43. Averch and Johnson's argument
  44. A handsome application of theory of monopoly Figure 1 denotes the firm's production where capital x1 is plotted on the horizontal axis and labor x2 on the vertical axis. The market or "social" cost of capital and labor generates the isocost curve A and the unregulated firm would move along expansion path 1 where market cost is minimized for any given output. With regulation, however, the cost of capital to the firm-the "private" cost is lower than the market cost. For each additional unit of capital input, the firm is permitted to earn a profit. The firm moves along expansion path 2.
More Related