660 likes | 786 Vues
Competitive Nonlinear Pricing in Duopoly Equilibrium: The Early U.S. Cellular Telephone Industry. Eugenio J. Miravete University of Pennsylvania & CEPR Lars-Hendrik R öller WZB, Humboldt University & CEPR (Chief Competition Economist, European Commission) This version: February 24, 2005.
E N D
Competitive Nonlinear Pricing in Duopoly Equilibrium: The Early U.S. Cellular Telephone Industry Eugenio J. Miravete University of Pennsylvania & CEPR Lars-Hendrik Röller WZB, Humboldt University & CEPR (Chief Competition Economist, European Commission) This version: February 24, 2005
Road Map • Motivation • Literature Review • The Data • Model Description • Econometric Implementation • Policy Evaluations • Things that still need to be done.
Motivation • Nonlinear pricing under competition: • Abundant evidence that firms engage in price discrimination practices even when they operate in competitive environments. • Business practices have not been matched by theoretical models until very recently.
Identification Issues • What are the basic estimation problems of the NEIO? • Marginal cost data is very rarely available. • Price-cost margins have to be estimated together with demand and cost parameters. • They change with consumption level in nonlinear tariffs. • Difficulties concerning the identification of the actual competition regime.
Our Approach • How do we incorporate the features of second degree price discrimination into the estimation of a structural equilibrium model of nonlinear pricing competition? • Nonparametric identification: Provided a given specification of demand, there is a one-to-one mapping between the distribution of types and the optimal nonlinear tariff. • Then we can make use of the information contained in the SHAPE of the tariffs offered by competing firms. • We assume Nash equilibrium in nonlinear tariffs.
Modeling Choices • Several approaches are possible to deal with nonlinear pricing competition:
Literature Review • Second degree price discrimination (reduced form): • Shepard, JPE´91: Full service vs. self-service gasoline. • Borenstein, RAND´91: Leaded vs. unleaded gasoline. • Cohen, 2000: Packaging size of paper towels. • Non-uniform markup changes (reduced form): • Borenstein, RAND´89: Airline pricing. • Busse and Rysman, 2001: Advertisements in yellow pages. • Busse, JEMS´00: Similarity of cellular phone tariffs.
Literature Review • Second degree price discrimination (equilibrium models): • Clerides, IJIO´02: Inter-temporal pricing of books. • Leslie, 2000: Pricing of a Broadway theater. • Cohen, 2001: Packaging size of paper towels. • McManus, 2001: Pricing of specialty coffee (size), U.Va. • Ivaldi and Martimort, Rev. Ec. et Stat´94: Power in France. • Basaluzzo and Miravete, 2004. • Linear Pricing (conjectural variations approach): • Parker and Röller, RAND´97.
Goals • Provide with an operationally feasible method of estimation for competitive markets where price discrimination is common. • Minimize the data requirements. • Evaluate how non-uniform markups change with competition. Who benefits the most? • Incumbent vs. entrants. • Large vs. small customers. • Policy analysis: • Mergers, pricing restrictions, and other counterfactual evaluations.
Some Facts: World • Cellular phones are quintessential part of IT revolution of the 1990s. • Currently, there are 1.3 billion subscribers worldwide. • The number of wireless phones will surpass the number of fixed-line subscribes in 2002. • It currently accounts for more than 30% of the $1 trillion total worldwide telecommunications revenues.
Some Facts: U.S. • United States, 2001: • Market penetration of 45% with 136 million subscribers. • Sales: $60 billion. • Employment: 200,000 direct jobs. • United States, 1988: • 1.6 million subscribers. • Sales: $2 billion. • Employment: 9,000 direct jobs. • Average monthly bill: $98.02.
Market Definition • Technological constraint: Scarce radio spectrum. • Solution: • Service areas divided in small cells served by its own low-powered transmitter. It allows this frequency to carry a different call in a non-adjacent cell. • A mobile telephone switching office maintains a continuous transmission when customers move to a cell that uses a different frequency. • FCC design of the early US cellular market: • Define 305 non-overlapping markets SMSAs. • Assign 50 MHz in the 800 MHz band for cellular services. • Wireline license: fixed line carriers in that area (Block B). • Non-wireline license: any other US citizen or company (Block A).
Market Definition: SMSA • It includes a central city or urbanized area of at least 50,000 people. • It also includes the county containing the central city and other contiguous counties with strong economic and social ties to the central city. • US Census (1990): • 76% of the population. • 16% of the land.
Sources: Tariff Plans • Cellular Price and Marketing Letter, Information Enterprises: • Pricing plans information reported by firms between August of 1984 and August of 1988. • Price plans are typically two-part tariffs with quantity discounts. • The number of plans varies from 1 to 9. • Plans normally include a peak-load component and airtime allowance. • Our focus: Retail market and peak period.
Sources: Market Size • Cellular Business, various issues, 1984-1988: • Cell sites. • Start-up date. • Remarks: • Output level is not directly observable. • Each cell site represents between 1,100 to 1,300 subscribers. • In a sample of 22 observations in 8 markets between 1985 and 1987, the correlation between number of cells and subscribers was about 0.92. • Market shares of competing firms are not known (except for the above mentioned markets).
Demand • Duopoly. Horizontally differentiated products: • Monopoly:
Distribution of Types • Burr type XII distribution: • Market specific markups:
Cost • Cost function: • Marginal cost specification:
Monopoly Solution • The monopolist solves the following mechanism: • Optimal tariff: • Optimal purchase:
Monopoly: Stochastic Structure • First stage quadratic approximation: • Measurement errors: Optional two-part tariffs vs. fully nonlinear tariff. • Interpretation of first stage coefficients:
How does the model work? 0 AIRTIME 500
Identification of Structural Param. • Highest consumer type: • Distribution parameter: • Marginal cost:
Participation Constraint • Marginal consumer type: • Determinants of participation:
Duopoly: Quadratic Tariffs • Basic assumption: • Redefinition of types:
Duopoly: Distribution of Types • Joint Distribution of types (Sarmanov): • Marginal Distribution of Types (Burr type XII):
Duopoly: Solution • Duopolist 1 solves the following mechanism: • Optimal tariff payment and purchase:
Duopoly: Stochastic Structure • First stage regressions: • Measurement errors: Optional two-part tariffs vs. fully nonlinear tariff. • Interpretation of first stage regression estimates:
Identification of Structural Param. • Highest consumer type: • Marginal consumer type:
Identification of Structural Param. • Distribution parameters (implements Nash perfection): • Marginal cost:
Further Identification Restrictions • Reduced form parameters: • Structural parameters of interest: • Still need to fix:
Estimation of Demand Parameters • Makes use of a smaller sample (of the largest markets) for which the number of subscribers of both firms is available for a couple of years. • It is assumed that consumers do not differ in their substitution pattern conditional on their observed characteristics. • System estimation from the necessary conditions of consumption: