1 / 58

Externalities

Externalities. Chapter 21. Introduction. Driving an automobile is probably a household’s most polluting activity Efforts since 1970 have greatly reduced typical vehicle emissions However, number of miles driven has more than doubled Offset benefits of controlling emissions

liam
Télécharger la présentation

Externalities

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Externalities Chapter 21

  2. Introduction • Driving an automobile is probably a household’s most polluting activity • Efforts since 1970 have greatly reduced typical vehicle emissions • However, number of miles driven has more than doubled • Offset benefits of controlling emissions • Net result is only a small reduction in automobile pollutants • Cause of automobile pollution is a major market failure in presence of an externality (pollution) resulting from missing markets • With missing markets, signals in form of market prices do not exist to reveal consumer preferences for society’s allocation of resources

  3. Introduction • If well-defined property rights exist, markets will generally occur for externalities • Reduces necessity for mechanisms designed to correct externality-generated inefficiencies • One role for government is to provide a legal system to support well-defined property rights for all of society’s resources • We investigate property rights and consequences of externalities resulting from ill-defined property rights • Then broadly classify externalities as either bilateral or multilateral • Discuss inefficiencies associated with bilateral externalities • Address enforceable property rights (given Coase Theorem) as a means for resolving these inefficiencies

  4. Introduction • Coase Theorem states • If a market can be created for an externality, an efficient outcome will result regardless of how well-defined property rights are allocated • We investigate markets where Coase Theorem does not hold • Discuss issue of multilateral externalities • Evaluate government policies involving quotas, taxes, and fostering markets for externalities (eliminating missing markets) as tools for addressing market inefficiencies • Government agencies develop mechanisms that assign property rights and regulate agent behavior • Enforcing policies through penalties for noncompliance and dividends for compliance • However, government mechanisms may not always result in improving social welfare • Such mechanisms can only result in alternative second-best Pareto-efficient allocations

  5. Introduction • Opportunity cost of allocating resources toward establishing and maintaining mechanisms may exceed cost of inefficiency associated with some externalities • Existence of opportunity cost implies that there are still externalities at some allocation where social welfare is maximized • Applied economists are active in estimating costs and benefits of alternative mechanisms for addressing externalities • Aim in chapter is not to determine least-cost allocation for removing an externality • But to understand why ill-defined property rights result in missing markets for commodities and resulting externalities • Can determine optimal level of an externality and minimum cost of achieving a given externality level

  6. Externalities Defined • An externality (z) is present whenever some agent’s (say, A’s) utility or production technology includes commodities whose amounts are determined by other agents • Without particular attention to effect on A’s welfare • Definition rules out any market-price affects on agents’ utility or production, called pecuniary externalities • Arise when external effect is transmitted through price changes • A pecuniary externality does not cause a market failure • For example, suppose a new firm enters a market and drives up rental price of land • Market for land provides a mechanism by which parties can bid for land • Resulting prices will reflect value of land in its various uses

  7. Externalities Defined • Without pecuniary externalities price signals would fail to sustain an efficient allocation • Consumers relying on firms for supply of commodities are not externalities • Deliberately affecting welfare of others is not an externality • For example, deliberate criminal actions against agents are not externalities • However, waiting for someone who is not particularly concerned about your welfare is an externality

  8. Property Rights • A bundle of entitlements defining an owner’s rights, privileges, and limitations for use of a resource • For example, in many cities owning a plot of land may give you entitlement to build a house but not drill a well • Entitlements vary considerably • From being very restrictive in a planned community to essentially no restrictions in some rural areas • A well-defined structure of property rights will provide incentives for efficient allocation of resources

  9. Property Rights • Following list is one set of well-defined private-property rights that results in a Pareto-efficient allocation • Universality • All resources are privately owned and all entitlements completely specified • Exclusivity • All benefits and costs from owning and employing resources accrue to owner • Transferability • All property rights are transferable from one owner to another in a voluntary exchange • Enforceability • Property rights are secure from involuntary seizure or encroachment by others

  10. Property Rights • Previously we implicitly assumed well-defined property rights existed • We demonstrated that perfectly competitive markets yield an efficient price system for resource allocation • Such a system is where producers maximize their profits and households maximize their utility • Given their respective resource constraints and current state of technology • Presence of externalities violates assumption of well-defined property rights • For example, building a cabin that blocks neighbor’s view of lake results in a cost that accrues to neighbor • With externalities, household preferences for commodities are not defined solely over bundle of commodities that it has ability to choose

  11. Property Rights • Assumption of firms freely choosing inputs is also violated with presence of production externalities • Generally, consumption or production externalities exist when agents (households and firms) are directly affected by actions (external effects) of other agents • Examples are • Presence of other vehicles on a congested highway (negative externality) • Sight of a neighbor’s flower garden (positive externality)

  12. Property Rights • When externalities exist, perfectly competitive equilibrium does not correspond with a Pareto-optimal allocation • A common property exists when no individual agent has property entitlements • Agent cannot employ resource for individual gain • In a communist economy, all society’s resources are considered common property • In a centrally planned socialist economy, state (government) has property entitlements and controls property (resource) allocation for common good of society • In a free-market economy, property entitlements are vested privately with individual agents • Leading to private property as dominant form of property rights

  13. Bilateral Externalities • Where one agent’s utility or profit is affected by another agent’s actions • Agents could be two firms with their production technologies linked • Firms could be producing either same or different outputs • For example, firms could be a chemical plant and a kayak rental company located on the same river • Alternatively, agents could be two households or one firm and a household • For example, two households living in a duplex where one household enjoys loud music

  14. Bilateral Externalities • For expository purposes, we will assume agents are firms • With one firm experiencing a negative externality from the other • Rather than well-defined property rights, assume Firm 1’s short-run total cost function is a function of marketable output q1 and a nonmarket output (externality) z, STC1(q1, z) • For example, q1 could be production of steel and z the associated river water pollution • Assuming Stage II of production for q1, associated marginal cost curve, ∂STC1/∂q1 = SMC1 > 0 • Has a positive slope, ∂SMC1/∂q1 > 0 • For externality z, ∂STC1/∂z < 0 • Increasing z will decrease cost of production • Represents a marginal benefit to firm

  15. Bilateral Externalities • Define marginal benefit as marginal benefit of the externality (MBE) • MBE = -∂STC1/∂Z > 0 • Associated MBE curve is illustrated in Figure 21.1, given Law of Diminishing Marginal Returns • As z increases, MBE declines • Given a missing market for z, there is no positive market price for z • A profit-maximizing firm would produce where ∂STC1/∂z = 0

  16. Figure 21.1 Negative externality

  17. Bilateral Externalities • An increase in costs with no associated change in revenue will decrease profit • Level of z that minimizes costs is ∂STC1/∂z = 0 • Assume firm 2’s short-run total cost function is directly affected by firm 1’s nonmarket output z, STC2(q2, z) • q2 denotes Firm 2’s marketable output, kayak rentals • Firm 2’s cost of producing q2 is directly affected by amount of z firm 1 produces • A negative externality implies ∂STC2/∂z > 0 • An increase in z increases STC2 and depresses profit • Partial ∂STC2/∂z > 0 is called marginal social cost (MSC) of externality • Illustrated in Figure 21.1 • Positive slope associated with MSC indicates • As z increases, marginal social cost increases • ∂MSC/∂z > 0 and ∂2MSC/∂z2 > 0 • Firm 2’s costs are increased by an increase in z at an increasing rate • For example, the river may be able to assimilate initial increases in water pollution, so MSC of water pollution for kayaking is low • However, as water pollution increases, capacity of river for assimilating pollution may be exceeded, resulting in marginal cost for the kayak firm increasing at an increasing rate

  18. Bilateral Externalities • Positive slope associated with MSC indicates • As z increases, marginal social cost increases • ∂MSC/∂z > 0 and ∂2MSC/∂z2 > 0 • Firm 2’s costs are increased by an increase in z at an increasing rate • For example, river may be able to assimilate initial increases in water pollution • MSC of water pollution for kayaking is low • However, as water pollution increases, capacity of river for assimilating pollution may be exceeded • Resulting in marginal cost for kayak firm increasing at an increasing rate

  19. Independent Decision Making • In its profit maximization, firm 1 has control over both q1 and z • p1 is per-unit price firm 1 receives for its output, q1 • Since z is a nonmarket output, there is no associated market price • F.O.C.s are • ∂1/∂q1 = p1 – SMB1(q1, z) = 0 • Discussed in Chapter 9 and illustrated in Figure 21.1 • ∂1/∂z = -∂STC1(q1, z)/∂z = 0 • Establishes cost-minimizing level of z as a necessary condition for profit maximization

  20. Independent Decision Making • Level of externality z should be adjusted to point where additional reduction in cost of generating an additional unit of z is zero • Solving F.O.C.s simultaneously for z and q1 results in their optimal levels zP and qP1 • Figure 21.1 illustrates this optimal solution • zP is associated with -∂STC1/∂z = MBE = 0 and qP1 with SMC1 = p1 • For its profit maximization, firm 2 only has control over its output, q2, but production of q2 is influenced by externality z, so • p2 is per-unit price of q2 • F.O.C. is • ∂2/∂q2 = p2 – SMC2(q2, z) = 0 • Establishes price equaling marginal cost as a condition for profit maximization

  21. Independent Decision Making • Externality results from firm 2 having no control over z, which affects its production • Firm 1 controls level of z and has no incentive to consider effect z has on firm 2’s production • When firm 2’s additional social cost, MSC, associated with firm 1’s pollution, z, is not considered by firm 1, an inefficient high level of pollution may result • At zP in Figure 21.1, MSC > MBE • Decreasing z will subtract more from cost than from benefits • Not considering additional social costs or benefits from an externality generally results in an inefficient allocation of resources

  22. Dependent (Joint) Decision Making • Internalizing social costs of a negative externality into agent’s decisions • Results in a Pareto-efficient allocation of resources • Internalization of social costs results in firm 1 taking into consideration impact its production decisions have on firm 2’s production possibilities • With this consideration, output z is no longer an externality • All effects of z are now internalized into firm 1’s production decisions • Accomplished by maximizing joint profit of the two firms ( = 1 + 2) • Equivalent to two firms merging to form one firm that produces marketable outputs q1 and q2, with associated prices p1 and p2, along with nonmarket output z • With joint action, there is no longer an externality • Additional social costs are now internalized within this one firm

  23. Dependent (Joint) Decision Making • Mathematically, joint profit maximization is • F.O.C.s are • ∂/∂q1 = p1 – SMCJ1(q1, z) = 0 • ∂/q2 = p2 – SMCJ2(q2, z) = 0 • ∂/∂z = -∂STC1(q1,z)/∂z - ∂STC2(q2, z)/ ∂z = 0 • SMCJj is short-run marginal joint cost of producing qj, j = 1, 2 • First two F.O.C.s are same as when firms act privately • A perfectly competitive firm equates price to marginal cost • Under joint action, optimal levels of q1 and q2, (qJ1 and qJ2) are where price is equated with marginal cost • For a negative externality, qJ1 < qP1, given z increases costs for producing q2

  24. Dependent (Joint) Decision Making • Last F.O.C. differs from independent conditions where firms act privately • Now optimal levels of q1, q2, and z depend on effect z has on firm 2’s costs • Figure 21.1 illustrates optimal levels of z and q1 • Instead of setting ∂STC1/∂z equal to zero, joint production sets -STC1/∂z equal to marginal social cost • -∂STC1(q1, z)/∂z = ∂STC2(q2, z)/ ∂z • MBEJ = MSC • MBEJ is marginal joint benefit of externality from joint production of q1 and q2 • Joint action will result in firm 1 decreasing level of z below point where MBE = 0 • Marginal social cost derived from firm 2 is now internalized into decision process

  25. Dependent (Joint) Decision Making • Difference between private and joint optimal solution is illustrated in Figure 21.1 • Optimal level of z decreases, from zP to zJ, along with a decrease in the optimal level of output, from qP1 to qJ1 • Firm 1’s short-run marginal cost of producing q1 shifts to the left, from SMC1 to SMCJ1 • Given increased cost of internalizing production of z • Similarly, firm 1’s marginal benefit of externality shifts to left, to MBEJ, given decrease in q1 • Through internalization, firm 1 pays a cost for producing z • At Pareto-efficient level of z, zJ, amount firm 1 is willing to pay for producing an additional unit of z is equal to firm 2’s additional costs associated with this additional unit of z • Note that if firm 2’s cost of producing q2 is independent of z, no externality exists • Firm 2’s cost associated with z is zero • Firm 1 will again equate additional cost of producing an additional unit of z to zero

  26. Resolving Externality Inefficiency • In February 2002, Oakland County International Airport in Waterford, Michigan, helped 650 residents to sound insulate and vibration reinforce their homes against airplane takeoffs and landings • Such solutions to externality inefficiencies are possible when conditions allow agents to negotiate an optimal solution • Providing favorable negotiating conditions is one approach to mitigating inefficiencies associated with externalities • Based on these negotiations, a market for externality is then established • For example, suppose for a negative externality z, enforceable property rights are established where firm 2 is assigned rights to production level of z (noise) • Firm 1 is unable to produce z without firm 2’s approval

  27. Resolving Externality Inefficiency • Denote total price (fee) for z units that firm 2 charges firm 1 as Fee • For profit maximization, firm 2 will determine level of Fee • Where firm 1 is indifferent between paying Fee to produce z units of externality or not producing any of the externality • If firm 2 charges a price below Fee, firm 1 will still produce z units • An increase in Fee will enhance firm 2’s profits without changing level of z • Increasing Fee transfers some of firm 1’s producer surplus in production of z to firm 2 • Firm 2 will increase Fee to point where all producer surplus from producing z units is absorbed by Fee • At this point, firm 1 is indifferent between paying Fee to produce z units or not producing any z

  28. Resolving Externality Inefficiency • Mathematically, this occurs where • 1(q1, z) – Fee = 1(q01, 0) • p1q1 – STC1(q1, z) – Fee = p1,q01 – STC1(q01, 0) • q01 represents optimal level of output given z = 0 • Firm 2 will then maximize profits subject to level of Fee where firm 1 is indifferent • Solving for Fee in the constraint and substituting into objective function yields

  29. Resolving Externality Inefficiency • F.O.C.s are • ∂2/∂q2 = p2 – SMCJ2 = 0 • ∂2/∂z = -∂STC2(q2, z)/∂z - ∂STC1(q1, z)/∂z = 0 = -MSC + MBEJ = 0 • Optimal levels for q2 and z are same solutions for joint production, zJ and qJ2 • Given this charge, Fee, for producing zJ units of a negative externality, firm 1’s profit-maximizing problem is • F.O.C. is • ∂1/∂q1 = p1 – SMCJ1 = 0 • F.O.C.s are identical to F.O.C.s for joint profit maximization • By assigning a property right to z, a market is created for z • Allows a firm to charge a price for its production of z • Resulting solution is the same optimal solution obtained under joint action, zJ

  30. Resolving Externality Inefficiency • Coase Theorem • If trade of an externality can occur (a market exists) • Bargaining will lead to an efficient outcome no matter how property rights are allocated • Assumes there are no transaction costs associated with bargaining • Any asymmetry in information between buyer and seller can cause transaction costs • Will not result in an efficient outcome no matter how property rights are allocated • Specifically, suppose firm 1 now has property rights to produce as much of the externality z as it desires • In absence of any trading, firm 1 will select private level of z, zP • Firm 2 will offer to pay firm 1 to move from firm 1’s private solution zP to joint-optimal solution zJ

  31. Resolving Externality Inefficiency • Firm 1 will be indifferent between producing an alternative level of z and receiving S as payment from firm 2 or producing zP and receiving no payment • 1(q1, z) + S = 1(qP1, zP) • p1q1 – STC1(q1, z) + S = p1qP1 – STC1(qP1, zP) • Firm 2 will then maximize profits, subject to levels of S, where firm 1 is indifferent

  32. Resolving Externality Inefficiency • Solving for S in the constraint and substituting into objective function yields • F.O.C.s are • ∂2/∂q2 = p2 – SMCJ2 = 0 • ∂2/∂z = -∂STC2(q2, z)/∂z - ∂STC1(q1, z)/∂z = 0 • Again, optimal levels for q2 and z are the same as in joint production, zJ and qJ2

  33. Resolving Externality Inefficiency • Firm 1’s profit-maximizing problem is • F.O.C. is • ∂1/∂q1 = p1 – SMCJ1 = 0 • Exactly the same optimal result as when property rights are controlled by firm 2 or with joint production • Given well-defined property rights and that agents can bargain with essentially zero transaction costs, resulting solution will be Pareto efficient • In practice, it is rare to find externalities with these characteristics • Normally, a profit incentive exists to either internalize the externality by merging or establish a market for the externality • Thus, market forces tend to remove any possible existence of a bilateral externality

  34. Resolving Externality Inefficiency • There are distributional effects that depend on assignment of property rights • Property rights are a form of initial endowments, which do have market value • For example, even though Coase Theorem states that optimal levels of z, q1, and q2 remain unaffected by property rights assignment • Resulting profit levels of firms are affected • When an agent is bestowed property right, its benefits will not decrease • Potential exists for enhancing benefits • Greater control over property rights improves bargaining power of an agent and, hence, potential rewards • Distribution of benefits can change with assignment of property rights • A market with well-defined property rights and essentially zero transaction costs will provide a Pareto-optimal allocation • Any improvement in social welfare is dependent on equity impacts of resulting allocation

  35. Multilateral Externalities • Decreasing automobile emissions can have a major impact on air quality and on asthma in children • This example illustrates multilateral externalities • Far more common than bilateral externalities • Numerous agents create transaction costs associated with ill-defined property rights • Obstruct market from internalizing externalities • Coase Theorem no longer holds under these transaction costs • Efforts to internalize these externalities may require some type of government intervention into markets

  36. Government Policies • Government actions to mitigate inefficient exploitation of resources have taken a number of forms • One policy is to instill some form of private-property rights on a common-property resource • For example, in western U.S., common- property problem of livestock overgrazing was addressed by issuing grazing permits • Ranchers who own grazing permits are allowed to use public rangeland for a set fee • Original grazing permits issued by state and federal agencies were freely given to ranchers • Common property of public lands was transferred to private ownership • Without a permit, one could not use public land for its major usegrazing • Permits acquired a market value through their incorporation into land value of ranch holding permits • Policy of granting private-property rights to common property may result in improving economic efficiency • However, it raises equity issues in terms of enhancing ranchers’ endowments at expense of other agents

  37. Permit System • Trading of emission permits represents a government management tool for a common property • Government controls resource and establishes barriers to prevent agents from exacting resource unless licensed by the government • For example, government may issue a permit to extract a certain quantity and/or size of a resource • Fishing and hunting licenses are examples

  38. Permit System • A permit system can also be employed for reducing a firm’s undesirable emissions that adversely affect air and water quality • Prior to generating a negative externality firm would be required to obtain a permit • Number of permits can be limited to achieve some target level • Allocation of permits transfers certain property rights to permit holder • In the case of a hunting permit, hunter pays for this transfer of property right • In terms of firms generating some negative externality, they may be issued permits at or below their historical emissions level • Given they possess a history of quasi-property rights to emission releases

  39. Permit System • Permits that can be traded (called marketable permits), create a market for permits with an associated equilibrium price • If a firm’s marginal cost of reducing emissions is greater than market price for a permit to release emissions • It would minimize cost by purchasing permit and releasing emissions • If its marginal cost is less than market price, it would minimize cost by selling permits and reducing its emissions • In equilibrium, each firm’s marginal cost of reducing emissions would be equal to market price for permits

  40. Permit System • Specifically, let’s consider two firms engaged in generating a negative externality • Let z1 and z2 represent emission levels of firm 1 and firm 2, respectively, with associated short-run total cost functions STC1(q1, z1) and STC2(q2, z2) • Assume target level of total emissions (zJ) is established, so zJ = z1 + z2 • Determine minimum cost of achieving emissions level zJ by • TC is total cost of reduced emissions

  41. Permit System • Lagrangian is • F.O.C.s are

  42. Permit System • Minimum-cost condition of achieving a zJ level of emissions is MBEJ1 = MBEJ2 = J • Firms’ short-run marginal benefits of emissions are set equal to J • In this case, Lagrange multiplier is marginal social cost of combined emissions by two firms, J = ∂TC/∂z • Setting this equal to each firm’s MBEJ yields minimum cost of establishing a zJ level of emissions • Illustrated in Figure 21.2 • Target level zJ is obtained at minimum cost with firm 1 and firm 2 generating zJ1 and zJ2 emissions, respectively

  43. Figure 21.2 Minimum cost of achieving a given emission level

  44. Permit System • Establishing a marketable permit system achieves this minimum social cost of emissions • Let pz represent per-unit equilibrium price of a permit and z01 and z02 initial level of permits for firms 1 and 2, respectively • zJ = z01 + z02 • With j = 1, 2, representing either of the firms, each firm will maximize profits as follows • When z0j - zj < 0, firm is using more permits than it was allocated • It will acquire additional permits in amount of (zj - z0j) at per-unit price of pz • If z0j – zj > 0, firm is not using all of its permit allocation • Will sell (z0j - zj) at per-unit price of pz

  45. Permit System • F.O.C.s are • ∂j/∂qj = pj – SMCJj(qj, zj) = 0 • Discussed in Chapter 9 • ∂j/∂zj = -∂STCj(qj, zj)/ ∂zj – pz = 0 = MBEJj – pz = 0, j = 1, 2 • Each firm equates their marginal benefit of emissions to pz • A major limitation of this marketable permit system exists when spatial distribution of externality generated by all firms is not uniform • If agents who are being affected by externalities are not uniformly affected by each firm • Permit system will result in some agents receiving even more of the externality • For example, assume households of type A are only affected by firm 1’s emissions and households of type B only by firm 2’s emissions • As illustrated in Figure 21.3, firm 1 sells permits to firm 2 • Thus, from initial emission levels (z01,z02) emissions for type A households are reduced at expense of type B households, who receive a higher emissions level • Although emissions level is now generated at a minimum cost, distribution of resulting emissions are not optimal

  46. Figure 21.3 Minimum cost of achieving a given emission level with marketable permits

  47. Taxes and Standards (Quotas) • If general knowledge exists about which firms can efficiently reduce a negative externality relative to other firms • Direct taxes or standards may be employed • Direct taxes on negative externalities have the theoretical foundation of the agent receiving an inefficient price for negative externality it is generating • With ill-defined property rights firms would receive a zero price for generation of emissions • An efficient price would be a tax equivalent to marginal social cost of negative externality • Profit-maximizing problem for firm j is • j is a per-unit tax for firm j on negative externality, z

  48. Taxes and Standards (Quotas) • Potentially, firms with differing production capabilities for efficiently reducing negative externality would face different tax levels • On a practical level, tax would generally be the same for firms with like production technologies within same industry and causing similar harm to other agents • Assuming a constant tax level across two firms, , F.O.C.s are • ∂j/∂qj = pj – SMCJj(qj, zj) = 0 • Discussed in Chapter 9 • ∂j/∂zj = -∂STCj(qj, zj)/∂zj -  = 0 = MBEJj -  = 0, j = 1, 2 • Firm j equates its marginal benefit of emission to  • Equating tax  to MSCj will yield an efficient level of emissions generation by each firm, zJj • Illustrated in Figure 21.4

  49. Figure 21.4 Pigouvian tax on emissions

  50. Taxes and Standards (Quotas) • As illustrated in Figure 21.1, if there is only one agent being affected by firm j’s emissions, then  = ∂STC2/∂zj • Given well-defined property rights, Coase Theorem would apply • No government-established price for market would be required for efficiency • However, as number of agents increase, even with well-defined property rights • Transaction costs of determining who are being affected by a negative externality increases • A government mechanism design in form of an emissions tax may be socially desirable • Such a tax, equivalent to MSC, is called a Pigouvian tax, after Arthur Pigou • Assuming general knowledge exists of which firms can efficiently reduce a negative externality relative to other firms • Pigouvian taxes directly associated possible spatial MSC would not have spatial distribution limitation associated with a permit system • Aside from the problem of acquiring this general knowledge for implementation • Pigouvian taxes are a Lindahl taxface same limitations • Agents facing a higher tax rate relative to others may not respond well to tax-discriminating nature of Pigouvian taxes

More Related