1 / 53

Externalities, Environmental Policy, and Public Goods

5. Externalities, Environmental Policy, and Public Goods. CHAPTER. Can Government Policies Help Protect the Environment?. Government policies to reduce pollution have proven to be controversial. Command and control — Can be costly and inefficient

minya
Télécharger la présentation

Externalities, Environmental Policy, and Public Goods

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. 5 Externalities, Environmental Policy, and Public Goods CHAPTER

  2. Can Government Policies Help Protect the Environment? • Government policies to reduce pollution have proven to be controversial. • Command and control— • Can be costly and inefficient • lower costs if they are allowed to choose the method. • Cap-and-trade – • a market-based approach such as RGGI, • relies on economic incentives rather than on administrative rules.

  3. Can Government Policies Help Protect the Environment? • The U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) plans to implement New Source Performance Standards (NSPS) for air pollution that would affect the entire nation.

  4. A market failure is when a market fails to coordinate choices in a way that achieves efficient use of resources. Possible sources of market failure Externalities Public goods Monopoly Market Failure Smoke from a factory is an example of an externality that may lead to market failure

  5. Externalities - the market fails to register fully costs and benefits. Externalities (Spillovers) • External costs: • When the actions of an individual or group incur acost to 3rd party. • External benefits: • Present when the actions of an individual or group generate benefits for3rdparties.

  6. sweater factory beach brewery

  7. S2(including external costs) Actual price and output Ideal price and output External Cost (Spillover) • All of the costs of production are not fully registered, so the supply curve understates the true cost of production. (Shifts left) Price S1 P2 P1 D Quantity/time Q1 Q2 • Too many units are produced. • Pollution problems are often a side effect.

  8. Actual price and output Ideal price and output D2(including external benefits) External Benefit • The demand curve understates the total value of the output. Price S1 P2 P1 D1 Quantity/time Q1 Q2 • From the viewpoint of efficiency, too few units may be produced.

  9. What’s the “Best” Level of Pollution? How do we know the “best” level of carbon emissions? If carbon dioxide emissions hurt the environment, should the government take action to eliminate them completely?

  10. Private costThe cost borne by the producer of a good or service. Social costThe total cost of producing a good or service, including both the private cost and any external cost. Private benefit The benefit received by the consumer of a good or service. Social benefit The total benefit from consuming a good or service, including both the private benefit and any external benefit. The Effect of Externalities

  11. How a Negative Externality in Production Reduces Economic Efficiency The Effect of Pollution on Economic Efficiency Because utilities do not bear the cost of acid rain, they produce electricity beyond the economically efficient level. Supply curve S1 represents just the marginal private cost that the utility has to pay.

  12. How a Negative Externality in Production Reduces Economic Efficiency The Effect of Pollution on Economic Efficiency Supply curve S2 represents the marginal social cost, which includes the costs to those affected by acid rain. If the supply curve were S2, rather than S1, market equilibrium would occur at price PEfficient and quantityQEfficient, the economically efficient level of output. But when the supply curve is S1, the market equilibrium occurs at price PMarket and quantity QMarket, where there is a deadweight loss equal to the area of the yellow triangle. Because of the deadweight loss, this equilibrium is not efficient.

  13. How a Positive Externality in Consumption Reduces Economic Efficiency The Effect of a Positive Externality on Economic Efficiency People who do not consume college educations can still benefit from them. The marginal social benefit from a college education is greater than the marginal private benefit to college students. Because only the marginal private benefit is represented in the market demand curve D1, the quantity of college educations produced, QMarket, is too low.

  14. How a Positive Externality in Consumption Reduces Economic Efficiency The Effect of a Positive Externality on Economic Efficiency If the market demand curve were D2 instead of D1, the level of college educations produced would be QEfficient, which is the efficient level. At the market equilibrium of QMarket, there is a deadweight loss equal to the area of the yellow triangle.

  15. What Causes Externalities? Property rightsThe rights individuals or businesses have to the exclusive use of their property, including the right to buy or sell it. Externalities and market failures result from incomplete property rights or from the difficulty of enforcing property rights in certain situations.

  16. Private Solutions to Externalities: The Coase Theorem Ronald Coase of the University of Chicago, winner of the 1991 Nobel Prize in Economics, under some circumstances, private solutions to the problem of externalities will occur. completely eliminating an externality usually is not economically efficient.

  17. The Clean Air Act: How a Government Policy Reduced Infant Mortality The benefit of reducing air pollution in 1970 was much higher than the benefit from a proportional reduction in air pollution would be today, when the level of pollution is much lower. In the two years following passage of the Clean Air Act, there was a sharp reduction in air pollution and also a reduction in infant mortality.

  18. The additional or the marginal benefit—received from eliminating another ton of sulfur dioxide declines as its emissions are reduced. The net benefitto society from reducing pollution is equal to the difference between the benefit of reducing pollution and the cost. To maximize the net benefit to society, pollution should be reduced up to the point where the marginal benefit from another ton of reduction is equal to the marginal cost.

  19. The Economically Efficient Level of Pollution Reduction The Marginal Benefit from Pollution Reduction Should Equal the Marginal Cost If the reduction of sulfur dioxide emissions is at 7.0 million tons per year, the marginal benefit of $250 per ton is greater than the marginal cost of $175 per ton. Further reductions in emissions will increase the net benefit to society.

  20. The Economically Efficient Level of Pollution Reduction The Marginal Benefit from Pollution Reduction Should Equal the Marginal Cost If the reduction of sulfur dioxide emissions is at 10.0 million tons, the marginal cost of $225 per ton is greater than the marginal benefit of $150 per ton. An increase in sulfur dioxide emissions will increase the net benefit to society.

  21. The Economically Efficient Level of Pollution Reduction The Marginal Benefit from Pollution Reduction Should Equal the Marginal Cost Only when the reduction is at 8.5 million tons is the marginal benefit equal to the marginal cost. This level is the economically efficient level of pollution reduction.

  22. The Fable of the Bees • British economist James Meade • there were positive externalities • in both apple growing and beekeeping. • Unless the government intervened, • the market would not supply enough • apple trees and beehives. • . • In Washington State, farmers with fruit orchards had been renting beehives to pollinate their trees since at least as early as 1917, and today honeybees pollinate more than $14 billion worth of crops annually, from blueberries in Maine all the way to almonds in California. Some apple growers and beekeepers make private arrangements to arrive at an economically efficient outcome.

  23. The Benefits of Reducing Pollution to the Optimal Level Are Greater than the Costs Reducing emissions from 7.0 to 8.5 million tons results in total benefits equal to the sum of the areas A and B under the marginal benefits curve.

  24. The Benefits of Reducing Pollution to the Optimal Level Are Greater than the Costs The total cost of this decrease in pollution is equal to the area B under the marginal cost curve. The total benefits are greater than the total costs by an amount equal to the area of triangle A.

  25. The Benefits of Reducing Pollution to the Optimal Level Are Greater than the Costs total benefits from reducing pollution are greater than the total costs, it’s possible for those receiving the benefits to arrive at a private agreement with polluters to pay them to reduce pollution.

  26. Do Property Rights Matter? In discussing the bargaining between the utilities and the people suffering the effects of their pollution, the victims could not legally enforce the right of their property not to be damaged. Would it make any difference if the utilities were legally liable? The only difference would be that the utilities would have an incentive to pay their victims for the right to pollute rather than the victims having to pay the utilities to reduce pollution. Either way, either side would pay to reduce pollution up to the point where the marginal benefit of the last ton of reduction is equal to the marginal cost.

  27. The Problem of Transactions Costs Transactions costsThe costs in time and other resources that parties incur in the process of agreeing to and carrying out an exchange of goods or services.

  28. The Coase Theorem Coase theorem - if transactions costs are low, private bargaining will result in an efficient solution to the problem of externalities.

  29. In general, private bargaining is most likely to reach an efficient outcome if the number of parties bargaining is small. In practice, private solutions to the problem of externalities will occur only if all parties to the agreement have full information about the costs and benefits associated with the externality and they are willing to accept a reasonable agreement.

  30. When There Is a Negative Externality, a Tax Can Lead to the Efficient Level of Output Because utilities do not bear the cost of acid rain, they produce electricity beyond the economically efficient level. If the government imposes a tax equal to the cost of acid rain, the utilities will internalize the externality. As a consequence, the supply curve will shift up, from S1 to S2.

  31. When There Is a Negative Externality, a Tax Can Lead to the Efficient Level of Output The market equilibrium quantity changes from QMarket, where an inefficiently high level of electricity is produced, to QEfficient, the economically efficient equilibrium quantity.

  32. When There Is a Negative Externality, a Tax Can Lead to the Efficient Level of Output The price of electricity will rise from PMarket—which does not include the cost of acid rain—to PEfficient—which does include the cost. Consumers pay the price PEfficient, while producers receive a price P, which is equal to PEfficient minus the amount of the tax.

  33. Using a Tax to Deal with a Negative Externality Some toilet paper plants discharge bleach into rivers and lakes, causing substantial environmental damage. The graph shows that at the optimal level of production, the difference between the marginal private cost and the marginal social cost is $50. Therefore, a tax of $50 per ton is required to shift the supply curve up from S1 to S2.

  34. Figure 5.6 When There Is a Positive Externality, a Subsidy Can Bring About the Efficient Level of Output People who do not consume college educations can benefit from them. As a result, the social benefit from a college education is greater than the private benefit to college students. If the government pays a subsidy equal to the external benefit, students will internalize the externality. The subsidy will cause the demand curve to shift up, from D1 to D2. As a result, the market equilibrium quantity will shift from QMarket, where an inefficiently low level of college educations is supplied, to QEfficient, the economically efficient equilibrium quantity. Producers receive the price PEfficient, while consumers pay a price P, which is equal to PEfficient minus the amount of the subsidy. Pigovian taxes and subsidies Government taxes and subsidies intended to bring about an efficient level of output in the presence of externalities.

  35. MakingtheConnection Should the Government Tax Cigarettes and Soda? Governments impose “sin taxes” on certain products. The effect of a tax on soda is shown in the figure. • Your Turn:Test your understanding by doing related problem 3.9 at the end of this chapter. MyEconLab

  36. Command-and-Control versus Market-Based Approaches Command-and-control approach An approach that involves the government imposing quantitative limits on the amount of pollution firms are allowed to emit or requiring firms to install specific pollution control devices. Are Tradable Emissions Allowances Licenses to Pollute? Some environmentalists have criticized tradable emissions allowances, arguing that just as the government does not issue licenses to rob banks or to drive drunk, it should not issue “licenses to pollute.” But this criticism ignores one of the central lessons of economics: Resources are scarce, and trade-offs exist. Resources that are spent on reducing one type of pollution are not available to reduce other types of pollution or for any other use. Because reducing acid rain using tradable emissions allowances has cost utilities $870 million rather than $7.4 billion as originally estimated, society has saved more than $6.5 billion per year.

  37. MakingtheConnection Can a Cap-and-Trade System Reduce Global Warming? Although CO2 emissions rose slightly during the first few years of a cap-and-trade plan set up in Europe in 2005, they should decline over time as the number of allowances is reduced. • Your Turn:Test your understanding by doing related problem 3.14 at the end of this chapter. MyEconLab

  38. Four Categories of Goods 5.4 LEARNING OBJECTIVE Explain how goods can be categorized on the basis of whether they are rival or excludable and use graphs to illustrate the efficient quantities of public goods and common resources.

  39. Public goods are: Public Goods • 1. jointly consumed– Individuals can simultaneously enjoy consumption of same product or service • If a public good is made available to one, it is simultaneously made available to others.

  40. Characteristics of a Public Good • 2. non-excludable– Consumption of the good is not able to be restricted to the customers who pay for it • Because those who do not pay can not be excluded, no one has much of an incentive to pay for such goods; each has an incentive to become afree rider. • Free rider:– a person who receives the benefits of the good without helping to pay for its cost. • When a lot of people become free riders, too little of the good is produced.

  41. Examples of public goods: • national defense • radio and television broadcast signals • clean air.

  42. Question for Thought: • Which of the following are public goods? • (using the definition of a public good.) a. An anti-missile system surrounding Washington. a. An anti-missile system surrounding Washington. b. A fire department. c. Tennis courts. d. Shenandoah National Park. e. Elementary schools

  43. Rivalry The situation that occurs when one person’s consuming a unit of a good means no one else can consume it. Excludability The situation in which anyone who does not pay for a good cannot consume it. Figure 5.7 Four Categories of Goods Goods and services can be divided into four categories on the basis of whether people can be excluded from consuming them and whether they are rival in consumption. A good or service is rival in consumption if one person consuming a unit of a good means that another person cannot consume that unit.

  44. We next consider each of the four categories: • Private good. A good that is both rival and excludable. • Public good. A good that is both nonrival and nonexcludable. • Free riding Benefiting from a good without paying for it. • Quasi-public goods. Goods that are excludable but not rival. • Common resource. A good that is rival but not excludable.

  45. The Demand for a Public Good Figure 5.8 Constructing the Market Demand Curve for a Private Good The market demand curve for private goods is determined by adding horizontally the quantity of the good demanded at each price by each consumer. For instance, in panel (a), Jill demands 2 hamburgers when the price is $4.00, and in panel (b), Joe demands 4 hamburgers when the price is $4.00. So, a quantity of 6 hamburgers and a price of $4.00 is a point on the market demand curve in panel (c).

  46. Figure 5.9 Constructing the Demand Curve for a Public Good To find the demand curve for a public good, we add up the price at which each consumer is willing to purchase each quantity of the good. In panel (a), Jill is willing to pay $8 per hour for a security guard to provide 10 hours of protection. In panel (b), Joe is willing to pay $10 for that level of protection. Therefore, in panel (c), the price of $18 per hour and the quantity of 10 hours will be a point on the demand curve for security guard services.

  47. The Optimal Quantity of a Public Good Figure 5.10 The optimal quantity of a public good is produced where the sum of consumer surplus and producer surplus is maximized, which occurs where the demand curve intersects the supply curve. In this case, the optimal quantity of security guard services is 15 hours, at a price of $9 per hour.

  48. Solved Problem 5.4 Determining the Optimal Level of Public Goods Jill and Joe are in need of security guard services. Their demand schedules are as follows: The supply schedule is as follows: a. Draw a graph that shows the optimal level of security guard services. Be sure to label the curves on the graph. b. Briefly explain why 8 hours of security guard protection is not an optimal quantity.

  49. Solved Problem 5.4 Determining the Optimal Level of Public Goods Solving the Problem Step 1: Review the chapter material. Step 2: Begin by deriving the demand curve or marginal social benefit curve for security guard services. To calculate the marginal social benefit of guard services, we need to add the prices that Jill and Joe are willing to pay at each quantity: Step 3: Answer part (a) by plotting the demand (marginal social benefit) and supply (marginal social cost) curves. Step 4: Answer part (b) by explaining why 8 hours of security guard protection is not an optimal quantity. For each hour beyond 6, the supply curve is above the demand curve, so the marginal social benefit received will be less than the marginal social cost of supplying these hours, resulting in a deadweight loss and a reduction in economic surplus. • Your Turn:For more practice, do related problem 4.4 at the end of this chapter. MyEconLab

  50. Common Resources Tragedy of the commons The tendency for a common resource to be overused. Figure 5.11 Overuse of a Common Resource For a common resource such as wood from a forest, the efficient level of use, QEfficient, is determined by the intersection of the demand curve—which represents the marginal benefit received by consumers—and S2, which represents the marginal social cost of cutting the wood. Because each individual tree cutter ignores the external cost, the equilibrium quantity of wood cut is QActual, which is greater than the efficient quantity. At the equilibrium level of output, there is a deadweight loss, as shown by the yellow triangle.

More Related