1 / 31

Week 7 Targeting and Food Aid

Development Issues in Africa Spring 2006. Week 7 Targeting and Food Aid. Contents. Targeting Public Transfer Self-targeting Causes of emergencies

Télécharger la présentation

Week 7 Targeting and Food Aid

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Development Issues in AfricaSpring 2006 Week 7 Targeting and Food Aid

  2. Contents • Targeting Public Transfer • Self-targeting • Causes of emergencies • Research Example: Jayne, Strauss, Yamano, and Molla, “Targeting of food aid in rural Ethiopia: chronic need or inertia?” Journal of Development Economics, vol. 68:247-288 • Research Example: Yamano, Alderman, and Christiaensen, “Child Growth, Shock, and Food Aid in rural Ethiopia” American Journal of Agricultural Economics

  3. Targeting Public Transfers • J.S. Mill characterized the design of effective public transfers as “one of giving the greatest amount of needful help with the smallest amount of undue reliance on it.” • Targeting has become important because governments are pressured to reduce poverty • Three issues: administrative costs, incentive effects, and political economy considerations

  4. The ideal solution Final income Net Transfer The marginal tax rate Poverty line Tax tax z y z 0 Original income (y) Aid (z - y) aid -z Slope is 1, suggesting an additional income completely replaces aid. Thus, poor households (y<z) have no incentives to earn income, while y <z. Original income (y)

  5. A uniform Transfer Final income (y+z) Net Transfer (z) tax z y 0 Original income (y) aid z -z z Slope is 0, suggesting an additional income is an additional unit increase. Thus, poor households (y<z) have incentives to earn income. Original income (y)

  6. Administrative costs • Targeting is not Free! • To target well, the provider needs to have good information about potential recipients. • It is, however, costly to obtain good information about who should be eligible and how much they should receive. R: the revenue required to implement a program A: administrative costs NP: leakages to the non-poor P: the effective transfer to the poor R = A + NP + P Targeting: F = P / (P + NP) The Administrative costs as a proportion of the revenues are C = A / (A + NP + P) C F 0 1

  7. Incentive problems: notice that under the ideal targeting, the poor do not have any incentive to work. • Targeting using indicators: assessing income is extremely difficult in developing worlds. Thus, programs use indicators, such as household size, land size, or assets. • One of the indicators could be region.

  8. Regional Targeting • To reduce the targeting costs, while maintaining a certain level of targeting, regional targeting is used: • Example: Suppose that there are two regions: Region A: 80 percent poor, population size N Region B: 20 percent poor, population size N • Scenario 1: Uniform distributions of aid in both regions A and B achieve 50 % targeting • Scenario 2: Uniform distributions of aid in region A only achieve 80 % targeting • Scenario 2: Uniform distributions of aid in region B only achieve 20 % targeting Concentrating the distributions only in region A reduces the administrative costs also.

  9. Self-targeting • Workfare: a screening argument and a deterrent argument • A screening argument: a work requirement can be used to discourage the non-needy who have high opportunity costs • A deterrent argument: imposing a work requirement may encourage certain kinds of behavior. Participants may invest in skill formation. • Transfers in kind: by providing poor quality goods, the programs can select the poor who can not afford better quality goods.

  10. Food-for-Work Program in Northern Ethiopia

  11. Conflicts and Famine • Most of Africa’s recent famines occurred within the context of armed conflicts (see handouts). • Without conflicts, relief systems can prevent famines by using food aid and other means (e.g., food crisis in Southern Africa in 2002; flood in Mozambique in 2001). • Thus, conflicts preventions and resolutions are among effective famine preventions and mitigation efforts.

  12. Food Aid: An Example of Food Crisis in Southern Africa • USAID estimated that up to 14.4 million people in six southern African countries (Lesotho, Malawi, Mozambique, Swaziland, Zambia, and Zimbabwe) would need food aid between 2002 and 2003 because of droughts. • This food crisis in Southern Africa was considered as worsened because farming system has been weakened by the HIV/AIDS epidemics. • See handouts. • Some evidence in next slides.

  13. Cereal Production per capita (Mt / person) in Southern Africa in 1997-2003

  14. Food Aid per capita (Mt / person) in Southern Africa in 2000-2003

  15. Sum of crop production and Food Aid per capita in Southern Africa in 2000-2003

  16. Research Example“Targeting of food aid in rural Ethiopia: chronic need or inertia?” Journal of Development Economics, vol. 68:247-288 • How well is food aid targeted to the poor? • Regional vs. Household targeting: Simulation Results

  17. Food Aid Targeting • Food aid is only weakly targeted to poor regions and households. • Free Distribution is better targeted to the poor than Food For Work. • Past food-aid reception matters: Chronic need or Inertia? • Regional or Household Targeting?

  18. Simulation: Various Targeting Scenarios

  19. Regional vs. Household Targeting • Regional Targeting: • Cost effective (information and implementations) • But high degrees of errors • A combination of two with better targeting at both levels is recommended

  20. Food Aid Distribution

  21. Table 1 Food Aid Distribution in Ethiopia Descriptive Analysis - The EA-level Analysis

  22. Results on Food Aid Allocation (Tobit) • Need Assessment 1984-88 Positive • C.V. of Long-run Rainfall Positive • EA-level Expenditure Negative • Peri-Urban Negative • Damaged Plot Areas Positive • Shocks account for only 13 percent of allocation • Inertia and long-run variables account for 87 percent

  23. Child Growth in Height“Child Growth, Shock, and Food Aid in rural Ethiopia” American Journal of Agricultural Economics, by Yamano, Alderman, and Christiaensen

  24. Figure 1. Child Growth in a Six-Month Period and Food Aid

  25. Table 5 Child Growth in Height: Children aged 6-24 months

  26. Implications • Plot damage has a negative impact on child growth • The average proportion of damaged plot areas in 1995/96 is 21 percent, indicating a 0.18 cm reduction (2.7%) • 50 percent >> 0.88 cm reduction (13%) • Food aid has a positive impact on child growth • A 1.6 cm increase in a typical food-aid-receiving community • A Simulation: 1% plot damage • 0.38 Birr more food aid, which increases growth by 0.027cm • 0.018 cm slower growth • Thus, food aid should be able to off-set the potential negative impact of plot damage

  27. Conclusions • Shocks reduce child growth, especially among children aged 6 to 24 months • Food aid has a positive impact on child growth and appears to be able to off-set the shocks • Yet, the child stunning remains high • Further studies are needed to understand why this is the case • Chronic factors (poor nutrition and health services) • Transitory factors (shocks and responses)

More Related