1 / 26

Multinational Corporations, Stateless Income, and Tax Havens

Multinational Corporations, Stateless Income, and Tax Havens. Sinclair Davidson. The public perception. Source: http:// www.huffingtonpost.co.uk/2012/12/10/google- starbucks-amazon-tax-spoof-logos_n_2270830.html.

reya
Télécharger la présentation

Multinational Corporations, Stateless Income, and Tax Havens

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Multinational Corporations, Stateless Income, and Tax Havens Sinclair Davidson

  2. The public perception • Source: http://www.huffingtonpost.co.uk/2012/12/10/google- starbucks-amazon-tax-spoof-logos_n_2270830.html • There has been a lot of public protest about well-known multi-national corporations not paying “their fair share” of tax. Economics, Finance and Marketing

  3. The public perception • Source: http://www.blog.rippedoffbritons.com/2012/10/starbucks-google-facebook-amazon-ibm.html Economics, Finance and Marketing

  4. The Claim The decline in corporate-tax collection in recent decades has contributed to budget deficits. It has also aggravated income inequality: a company’s shareholders ultimately pay its taxes, and with a smaller tax bill, shareholders, who tend to be much more affluent than the average American, see their wealth increase. “It’s clearly a broken system,” said Michelle Hanlon, an accounting professor at M.I.T. Corporate taxes burst into the spotlight last week, with the release of a Senate committee report on Apple’s tactics to reduce its tax payments. More quietly, but perhaps more significantly, the House Ways and Means Committee has begun work on a potential overhaul of the tax code. Edward D. Kleinbard, a tax expert and former Democratic Congressional aide, said he had been impressed so far by the seriousness of the committee’s work. • David Leonhardt, Who Will Crack the Code?, The New York Times, May 25, 2013. Economics, Finance and Marketing

  5. The Fiscal Challenge Economics, Finance and Marketing

  6. The Fiscal Challenge Economics, Finance and Marketing

  7. The Corporate Income Tax and Fiscal Illusion Economics, Finance and Marketing

  8. The Corporate Income Tax and Fiscal Illusion Economics, Finance and Marketing

  9. Is the Corporate Tax Base being eroded? Economics, Finance and Marketing

  10. Is the Corporate Tax Base being eroded? • Peter Birch Sørensen has provided a test where the ratio of corporate income tax revenue to GDP is decomposed into its component parts: R/Y=R/C*C/P*P/Y • R = corporate tax revenue, • Y is GDP, • C is total corporate profit and • P is total profit earned in the economy. • R/C is a proxy for the average effective corporate income tax rate, • C/P is the share of corporate profits and • P/Y is the profit share of the economy. Economics, Finance and Marketing

  11. Is the Corporate Tax Base being eroded? Economics, Finance and Marketing

  12. Is the Corporate Tax Base being eroded? • Australia Economics, Finance and Marketing

  13. Double Irish Dutch Sandwich • Source: AFR20 June 2013 http://www.afr.com/p/markets/gaping_legislative_loopholes_mean_twxDlS6YlGZ6qqNos31HbM Economics, Finance and Marketing

  14. A Critique of the Stateless Income Doctrine • Edward Kleinbard, Professor of Law at the University of Southern California, has developed the notion of “stateless income”. • Influential in the current debate. • Definition: • Income derived by a multinational group from business activities in a country other than the domicile (however defined) of the group’s ultimate parent company, but which is subject to tax only in a jurisdiction that is not the location of the customers or the factors of production through which the income was derived, and is not the domicile of the group’s parent company. • Complex and convoluted. • Stateless income thus can be understood as the movement of taxable income within a multinational group from high-tax to low-tax source countries without shifting the location of externally-supplied capital or activities involving third parties. Economics, Finance and Marketing

  15. A Critique of the Stateless Income Doctrine • Kleinbard claims that stateless income is not equivalent to capital mobility or aggressive transfer pricing. • “The phenomenon of stateless income risks appearing vague, and its analysis tedious”. • The fact, however, that some multinational corporations do not pay (very much, if any) corporate income tax in any one particular jurisdiction is necessary but not sufficient evidence of wrong-doing on the part of those corporations. • “Stateless persons wander a hostile globe, looking for asylum; by contrast, stateless income takes a bearing for any of a number of zero or low-tax jurisdictions, where it finds a ready welcome.” • The basic problem with Kleinbard’s argument isn’t that MNCs don’t pay tax but that they don’t pay tax in the US. Economics, Finance and Marketing

  16. A Critique of the Stateless Income Doctrine • The source of stateless income appears to be two-fold: • MNCs locate their valuable intellectual capital in those economies with legal regimes that value them most highly. • Highly mobile. • Easily expropriateable. • But … Kleinbard does not recognise this point. • Kleinbardviews the source of stateless income as being, “an inevitable by-product of fundamental international income tax norms” and “nations’ collective failure to agree on other critical international tax norms that would determine the “source” of income”. Economics, Finance and Marketing

  17. A Critique of the Stateless Income Doctrine • Kleinbard’s position is fragile: • “the recognition of the separate tax personas of different juridical persons”. • “the general practice of treating interest on indebtedness as deductible to the payor”. • “the norms of freedom of contract”. • It is the ready acceptance by countries of the fantastic notions that • (i) a wholly-owned subsidiary has a mind of its own with which to negotiate “arm’s-length” contractual terms with its parent, • (ii) capital provided to the subsidiary by the parent somehow becomes the property of an independent actor (the subsidiary) with which it can take business risks that for tax purposes are not simply assimilated into those borne by the parent (as both provider of the capital and ultimate economic owner of the assets acquired therewith), and • (iii) a multinational enterprise that exists as a global platform to exploit a core set of intangible assets best is analogized to wholly independent actors taking on limited and straightforward roles in a vertical chain of production or a horizontal array of distribution of a product. Economics, Finance and Marketing

  18. A Critique of the Stateless Income Doctrine • So what is he saying? • It is not at all clear that • separate tax personas, • deductibility of interest payments, • freedom of contract, • limited liability, and • the veil of incorporation, are “fantastic notions”. Economics, Finance and Marketing

  19. A Critique of the Stateless Income Doctrine • Realising that his argument is weak, Kleinbard is reduced to scare-mongering: • When unchecked, stateless income strips source countries (including the United States as the location of subsidiaries of foreign-controlled groups) of the tax revenues attributable to income generated in those jurisdictions. Its availability also distorts the investment decisions of multinational firms, and under current U.S. rules distorts a U.S. multinational firm’s decision whether to repatriate that stateless income back to the United States. • Problems: • Having just argued that the problem is a by-product of tax conventions stateless income is a definitional problem not base erosion. • He provides no evidence of distortion. • At worst this might be a governance problem not a tax problem. Economics, Finance and Marketing

  20. A Critique of the Stateless Income Doctrine • Kleinbard claims: • Stateless income “destroys any possible coherence to the concept of the geographic source of income, on which all territorial tax systems rely”. • But that is wrong: • Stateless income tax planning does not make geographic source incoherent – it transfers it from one location to another. • As the WSJ indicated: • “We wonder what the Irish think of the spectacle of an American Senator expressing outrage that an American company doesn't pay enough Irish taxes.” Economics, Finance and Marketing

  21. A Critique of the Stateless Income Doctrine • Kleinbard undervalues intellectual property. • “there is nothing in the [double Irish Dutch sandwich] structure that relies on any unique business model or asset of Google’s”. • As if Google’s business model itself is not intellectual property. • Why would firms choose to invest across a national border rather than simply export into that market, or licence production in another economy. • John Dunning argues that multinational firms own firm-specific intangible assets and can best exploit the value of those assets by investing across national borders. Economics, Finance and Marketing

  22. Tax Havens and Multinational Corporations • What sort of multinational corporations establish activities in low-tax jurisdictions? • Large firms with high shares of international activity are the most likely to have haven affiliates, and firms in industries characterized by high R&D intensities and significant volumes of intrafirm trade similarly exhibit the greatest demand for tax haven operations. • Mihir Desai, Fritz Foley and James Hines Jr., (2006a) • Does investment in low-tax jurisdictions crowd-out investment in high-tax jurisdictions? • No. Desai, Foley and Hines also report that tax haven activity increases economic activity in nearby non-tax haven economies. • Finally if income shifting is occurring, how large are the quantities of potential tax revenue involved? Economics, Finance and Marketing

  23. Tax Havens and Multinational Corporations • Finally if income shifting is occurring, how large are the quantities of potential tax revenue involved? • DhammikaDharmapala and Nadine Riedel investigate the amount of profit shifting that actually occurs using 5400 European multinational affiliates over the period 1995 – 2005. • The magnitude of the profit being shifted, however, is only two per cent of parent corporation profits. • Consistent with estimates in the literature of the gains to be made from tax harmonisation. Economics, Finance and Marketing

  24. Tax Harmonisation • Kleinbard has advocated tax harmonisation with a global corporate income tax rate of 25 per cent. Economics, Finance and Marketing

  25. Conclusions • There is no such thing as “stateless income”, rather there is income that the governments of the United Kingdom and the United States do not tax because under their own legal systems that income is not sourced in their economy. • When these governments complain about stateless income, the question rather should be, “Why do the owners of intellectual property not locate their property in your economy?”. • An implicit assumption of the stateless income doctrine is that multinational corporations maximise their value to society only when they pay tax. • The argument is that the corporate income tax base is being eroded by aggressive tax planning on the part of multinational corporations – yet the evidence to support this argument is lacking. Economics, Finance and Marketing

  26. Final word to the WSJ The Apple units are based in Ireland, so U.S. law does not consider them to be U.S. corporations subject to U.S. corporate tax. But since they are managed and controlled by Apple in the U.S., Irish law doesn't consider them Irish companies and thus they are also not subject to the 12.5% Irish corporate tax. This isn't alchemy; it's accountancy. … None of this required a Senate “investigation” to discover because Apple is constantly inspected by the IRS and other tax authorities. These tax collectors are well aware of Apple’s corporate structure, which has remained essentially the same since 1980. An Apple executive said Tuesday that the company's annual U.S. tax return adds up to a stack of paperwork more than two feet high. Review and Outlook, 2013, The Apple Tax Diversion: Senators beat up a U.S. success for following the tax laws they wrote, The Wall Street Journal, May 21, 2013. Economics, Finance and Marketing

More Related