1 / 48

Eco 383: PPT lecture slides, October 2006

Eco 383: PPT lecture slides, October 2006. Topics: Franchise finances Competitive balance and market size Player salaries, MRPL, and exploitation. Franchise finances: An introduction. Why we care:

shino
Télécharger la présentation

Eco 383: PPT lecture slides, October 2006

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Eco 383: PPT lecture slides, October 2006 • Topics: • Franchise finances • Competitive balance and market size • Player salaries, MRPL, and exploitation

  2. Franchise finances: An introduction • Why we care: • (1) To draw a conclusion about the health of the industry (MLB), we need to know about the health of individual firms (teams). • (2) Issue of whether the small-market teams can afford to field competitive teams. • If too many teams cannot compete, then demand for MLB will tend to fall.

  3. MLB’s 2000 report concluded that... • (1) 27 of the 30 MLB teams had cumulative operating losses in 1995-99. • (2) Small- and mid-market teams can’t compete, because they can’t afford to field very good teams.

  4. OPERATING PROFIT = total revenues - total costs same as “operating income” what we focus on reported in Forbes (1997-), Financial World (1990-96) PRE-TAX PROFIT = operating profit - interest costs* - “player depreciation” < operating profit declared to IRS (* interest costs could be from purchase of team, stadium debt…) Computing team profits

  5. Ways to hide a team’s profits • Claim “depreciation” of your players as a loss (over 5 years, up to 50% of what you paid for the team; legal under U.S. tax law). • Deduct the interest paid on team-related loans. • Related-party transactions: If you own another company that does business with the team, overcharge your team (or pay it too little) in those deals. • Featherbedding: Pay yourself (and friends and relatives) an excessive salary and claim it as a cost.

  6. Breakdown of team revenues (Forbes, 1998) • 40% tickets & suites • 34% broadcasting • 12% food, merchandise • 7% ads, sponsorship • 6% other

  7. Breakdown of team costsIn rough descending order of importance • Player salaries (~55% in 1992-2001) • Scouting & player development (farm teams…) • “General and administrative” / Team operations • (front office, manager, coaches…) • Marketing, publicity, ticket operations • Stadium operations • Contributions to MLB central fund • (MLB revenue-sharing; sums to $0)

  8. Estimated profitability of MLB teams(source: Forbes)

  9. Estimated profitability, cont’d

  10. Calculating a team’s (one-year)return on assets (ROA) ROA = % increase in estimated team value + (operating profit as % of previous year’s team value) Note well: Because operating profit is usually a very small fraction of team value, ROA will usually be very close to the one-year percent change in team value.

  11. To calculate ROA from the Forbes table ROA = (Operating income) (1 year change in value) + -------------------- | (Current value) | | ---------------- | | 1+(1 year change)| (Tip: Compute in decimal form, then convert to %.) Ex.: NY Yankees: Value: Current value (May 2006) = $1026 M Value: 1 year change = 8% (or .08) Operating income = -$50.0 M • --> ROA = .08 + (-50.0)/[(1026/1.08)] • = .08 + (-50)/(950) • = .08 + (-.053) • = .027, or 2.7%

  12. YES, say owners and commissioner (most notably in 2000-02) Selig: for 2001, a $232 M operating loss & a $519 M book loss 2000 report said 5 of 13 franchise sales in 1992-2000 were at a loss Selig: “We’ve run out of ‘greater fools’ ” weak resale market in 2001-02 Lately, Selig and owners are less negative, thanks in part to current CBA NO, say most independent researchers Forbes: for 2001, a $75 M operating profit Franchises normally sell at big profits; high rates of asset appreciation Weak resale market in 2001-02 was temporary and due to sluggish economy. Is the sky falling on MLB financially?

  13. What a difference a year makes:Baseball finances in 2003, 2004, & 2005

  14. Media ownership of teams • Ownership of teams by media companies, esp. TV stations, complicates the profit picture. • Media companies often buy teams as programming content, not as separate investments; synergy strategy. • Large operating losses may be OK if media company’s own profits go up. • Two media companies recently sold their teams. • (Fox) News Corp. sold Dodgers, Disney sold Angels • Time Warner looking to sell Braves? • MLB teams as unprofitable corporate divisions?

  15. Criteria for investments, and how MLB teams stack up • Rate of return (appreciation of asset value) • 12.4% in 1960-2002 (John Moag) • 8% in 1950-2000 (Rodney Fort) • 9% from time of purchase to 2004; average of 23 teams (Forbes) • stocks (benchmark): 6.9% in 1960-2002 • Safety (lack of risk) • Forbes, April 2004: 16 of 23 teams had long-term gains of 9% or more; 4 had gains of 5-7%; 2 had gains of 2-3%; one had loss of 2% • Operating losses are usually small but not uncommon. • stocks: returns are highly variable and often negative; but, can diversify. • Liquidity (convertibility into cash; resellability) • poor; selling a team takes many months if not years • stocks: very liquid, easy to resell • Cash flow • Minimal in relation to size of investment (ditto for stock dividends). • But, can be negative (whereas stockholders have limited liability).

  16. What is competitive balance?

  17. Blue Ribbon Panel report (2000): competitive balance exists when • “there are no chronically weak clubs because of MLB’s financial structural features” • a well-managed club has a reasonable hope of reaching postseason play and winning • (implies that finances and market size should have minimal effect)

  18. Why is competitive balance an economic issue?

  19. The demand for MLB will tend to fall if-- • too many teams cannot compete • fans perceive that the richest teams have an unfair advantage

  20. Simple measures of competitive balance • Standard deviation of team winning percentages • Number of WS or pennant winners, in comparison with-- • number of teams in league • previous years or intervals • Average number of games out of first place?

  21. MLB’s competitive balance, then & now • 1903-1950s: not much, but gradually improving • 1965-1976: improved more; amateur draft helped • 1977-early 1990s: peak of competitive balance • 1995-2001: competitive imbalance? • Regular season: strong correlation between payroll and W-L % • Postseason: • all WS winners were from top 25% of payrolls • only 4 teams from bottom 50% made postseason, won 5 games • 2002-2006 WS winners and payroll rank: • Angels (15th-highest), Marlins (26th) • Red Sox (2nd) • White Sox (13th), Cardinals (11th) or Tigers (14th)

  22. What is “market size”?

  23. Market size is based on REVENUES (both actual and potential). • Revenues are very dependent on the quality of the team’s product (wins, players, stadium, etc.), but also on local factors like • area population • area per-capita income • area level of interest in baseball (hard to measure) • Hard to separate team factors from local factors, actual from potential market size

  24. Two crude measures of market size • TOTAL REVENUES, as compared with the other MLB teams • ESTIMATED TEAM VALUE, as compared with the other MLB teams • more forward-looking, e.g., higher if team is about to move into new stadium • Which teams are “large market” (~top 4?), “mid-market,” “small market” (~bottom 5?)? • Market size perhaps cannot be measured precisely

  25. First 15 years of free agency (1977-91) saw unprecedented parity, several successful small-market teams Insignificant correlation between payroll and W-L % through mid-1990s Recent success of some small-market teams Market size is not static Yankees: 4 WS titles in 5 years (1996-2000) 1997-2006: statistically significant correlation between payroll, W-L % 1992-2006: Only one small-market, low-payroll team has won WS Collapse of Montreal Expos (well-run small-market team) Can the small-market teams compete?MAYBE MAYBE NOT

  26. Competitive balance in recent decades • Recall: • 1977-early 1990s: peak of competitive balance • 1995-2001: some pattern of competitive imbalance • Explanations: • Free agency (post-1976) helped comp. balance • Easier for also-rans to improve themselves with new talent • Rising salaries --> harder to keep championship teams intact • Growing revenue and wealth imbalance in 1990s • Growing importance of local media and stadium revenues • Value of MLB’s national TV deal fell 60% in 1994 • Increasing corporate (esp. media) ownership of teams

  27. Competitive balance in other pro sports • (NFL) National Football League: highest comp. balance • low concentration of championships (but MLB’s is lower now) • policies: ~70% of revenues are shared; hard salary cap; “unbalanced” schedule • lowest correlation between payroll and performance • (NHL) National Hockey League: ?????? • Pre-2004: in the middle: • low concentration of championships (1991-2002: 8 different teams) • little revenue sharing, no luxury tax, no salary cap • lower payroll-performance correlation than MLB or NBA • 2004-05: season-long lockout by owners, who got a salary cap • (NBA) National Basketball Association: least balanced • high concentration of championships (1991-2002: just 4 teams) • increasing standard deviation of win percentages since 1980

  28. The English Premier League (PL; soccer) • League membership not fixed (non-monopolistic) • no territorial rights • London: 9 PL teams since 1990 • Within the league, a hierarchy of divisions • bad high-division teams are relegated (demoted) • good low-division teams are promoted to higher ones • Comp. balance is mixed • good in terms of standard deviation of win percentages, upward mobility of teams • high championship concentration (Manchester United)

  29. How can be MLB’s competitive balance be increased? • Payroll cap / luxury tax? • Payroll cap might work, but is not feasible • Players’ union willing to strike to prevent one. • Owners have not asked for one since 1995. • MLB has a luxury tax on large payrolls, but threshold is too high to be binding for most teams • Increased revenue sharing? • Could work, but details are key: • What if teams use accounting tricks to hide revenues? • Incentive for low-revenue teams to improve themselves? • Part of current (2002-2006) Collective Bargaining Agreement.

  30. Player performance and salaries

  31. News flash:MLB players are highly paid • Average MLB salary = $2.87 M (April 2006) • Up 8.9% from previous year • About 10 times as high as in 1983 • Less than NBA ($4.5 M in 2003) • More than NHL ($1.6 M), NFL ($1.3 M) (in 2003) • Median MLB salary = $1,000,000 • Fluctuates a lot more than the average • Was $975,000 in 2000, fell to $800,000 in 2003 • 409 players making $1 M+, fewer than in 2000-2002

  32. marginal revenue product of labor (MRPL) • = the amount of revenue that an employee generates for his employer • standard economic answer to “How much is that employee worth?” • can be measured in yearly terms (salary), or in hourly terms (hourly wage) • marginal product of labor (MPL) = how much OUTPUT an employee produces

  33. MRP theory & player pay • First, note that athletes are not the only very highly-paid people in U.S. society • VOLUNTARY EXCHANGE = market transactions, including free-agent contracts, are agreed-upon by buyer and seller • Fort: “talent is hired to produce [wins] in the long run.” • perhaps more than just wins... • Mark McGwire, 1998: extra MRPL of $15M?

  34. A labor market under perfect competition: Assumptions • Many buyers, many sellers -- nobody has market power • No restrictions on pay or employment • No cartels among employers, no unions • Diminishing returns --> downward-sloping demand curve for labor • Upward-sloping supply curve for labor

  35. Notation (goes with blackboard notes): • L = # of workers ( = QL = quantity of labor) • w = wage ( = PL = price of labor) • SL = supply of labor • DL = demand for labor • MRPL = marginal revenue product of labor • MRPL = the amount of revenue that an additional worker generates for the firm

  36. Economic exploitation • MONOPSONY: a labor market with just one buyer • ECONOMIC EXPLOITATION • = difference between a worker’s marginal revenue product and his wage • = MRPL - w • In a monopsonistic labor market: • w < MRPL • w < w* (competitive wage)

  37. When the baseball players’labor market was a monopsony • Until 1976, when all players were under the reserve clause. • RESERVE CLAUSE: a provision in baseball’s rules that allowed owners to renew a player’s contract automatically for one year. • Players either re-signed with their teams after each season or retired (or were traded or released). • No free agency; no competitive bidding for players. • Held salaries down; average salary = $25,000 in 1969.

  38. Independence Day • July 1976: new Basic Agreement gives all players free agency after 6 years of service. • Salaries surged after 1976; up 42% in 1976-77 • Can use monopsony diagram to illustrate

  39. Baseball’s current system

  40. The amateur draft • MLB’s annual selection of the top amateur talent in the U.S. • Conducted each June. Worst teams draft first. • A player can deal only with the team that drafts him • Monopsonistic market. • In effect since 1965. • Before 1965, teams just signed amateur players as free agents. • Competitive market • Signing bonuses were often quite high. • Once the draft began in 1965, signing bonuses dropped dramatically.

  41. Baseball’s salary explosion, 1976-present • “Freedom and prosperity” • Shift from monopsony to competitive bidding was less sudden than it seems • Over time, more and more teams played the FA market • Collusion against FA’s held salaries down in mid-1980s • Salary arbitration (1973-) allowed 3rd-to-6th-year players to piggyback on FA salary scale • MLB revenues surged -- attendance rose, TV revenues soared, stadium revenues soared, ...

  42. Comparison of performance (MRPL) and salaries: • “Exploitation index” (EXPL) = MRPL/salary • Alternatively, “pay-for-performance index,” salary/MRPL • Zimbalist estimated this with 1986-89 data • How to measure MRPL?

  43. For hitters, the one common statistic with the highest correlation with team winning percentages is...

  44. “OPS”(On-base Plus Slugging pcts.) • = On-base percentage (OBP) + Slugging percentage (SLG) • = what Zimbalist uses a measure of hitters’ productivity, in computing MRPL’s • --> next steps: • estimate the player’s contribution to team winning percentage, based on wins as a function of OPS • estimate contribution of additional wins to team revenues

  45. Comparison of performance (MRPL) and salaries: • Younger players tend to be “exploited” (pay<MRPL) • Players with 6+ years of experience tend to be “overpaid” (pay>MRPL)

  46. Salary/MRPL, by service category (1986-89)

  47. Salary/MRPL: 2003 update(Source: Bill Felber of Total Baseball)

  48. How do we explain those systematically “overpaid” veterans? • Supply and demand: Even though most free agents are past their prime, teams still have holes to fill and supply of free agents is limited  mediocre free agents can command top dollar • Also of note: • Stats-based MRPL measure may be too narrow -- doesn’t count leadership, reputation, marquee value • Free-agent contracts are often long term  reduced incentive to work hard?

More Related