1 / 40

最適課稅、使用費率與經濟成長

最適課稅、使用費率與經濟成長. 洪福聲 陳建印. Motivation. Investment of public inputs can stimulate economic growth (Eberts, 1986; Garcia-Mila and McGuire, 1988; Aschauer, 1989; Barro, 1990; Kocherlakota and Yi, 1992) Public inputs: Rival vs. Non-rival Excludable vs. Non-excludable.

Télécharger la présentation

最適課稅、使用費率與經濟成長

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. 最適課稅、使用費率與經濟成長 洪福聲 陳建印

  2. Motivation • Investment of public inputs can stimulate economic growth (Eberts, 1986; Garcia-Mila and McGuire, 1988; Aschauer, 1989; Barro, 1990; Kocherlakota and Yi, 1992) • Public inputs: Rival vs. Non-rival Excludable vs. Non-excludable

  3. Pure public input: • Barro (1990):public input (flow) into producti- on function. • Futagami, Morita, and Shibata (1993): public input (stock) into production function. • The size of user fee of revenue is increasing for the governments in many countries (Borge, 1995; Dewees, 2002; Blomquist and Christiansen, 2005).

  4. Public input (subject to congestion ): • Barro and Sala-I-Martin (1992): income tax rate is superior to lump-sum taxation. • Glomm and Ravikumar (1994): optimal income tax rate (second best) is independent of the degree of congestion.

  5. Public Input (Excludability) • Borge (1995) 、Dewees(2002) 、Blomquist and Christiansen(2005) : In many countries there has been a recent trend towards more user fees. • Ott (2001): an increase in the degrees of congestion leads to an increase in the income tax rate, a decrease the user fee, and a decrease in the consumption tax rate. • Ott and Turnovsky(2006): the government provided two public inputs: excludable and non-excludable.

  6. The key feature that distinguishes our study from Ott (2001) and Ott and Turnovsky (2006) is the incentive effect of the user fee.

  7. Model Individual: Individual uses a technology given as (1) and are the actual levels of excludable public inputs and non-excludable public inputs, respectively.

  8. Excludable public inputs: (2a) :aggregate supply of excludable public inputs :aggregate capital stock :usage of excludable public inputs chosen by the individual :aggregate demand of excludable public inputs.

  9. Non-Excludable public inputs: (2b) :aggregate supply of excludable public inputs :usage of excludable public inputs chosen by the individual :aggregate demand of excludable public inputs.

  10. The utility function of a representative indivi- dual is given as (3) budget constraint is given as (4) : user fee : tax rate

  11. Government : government budget constraint is given by (5) where is total output of the economy. assume that (6a) and (6b)

  12. Equilibrium consequence under the centralized economy the social planner will realize that The production function faced by the social planner become (7) The resource constraint given as (8)

  13. The optimality conditions (9a) (9b) growth rate (10)

  14. Substitute eqs. (6a) and (6b) into eq. (7) (11) where (12) Growth rate (13)

  15. Proposition 1. Under a centralized economy, the optimal expenditure share of excludable public inputs is given as (14a) (14b) The growth rate of the economy under the centralized economy (15)

  16. Equilibrium consequence under the decentralized economy The optimality conditions (16a) (16b) or if (16c) (16d)

  17. growth rate of consumption (17) The production function faced by the individual (18)

  18. A comparison between eq. (18) and eq. (7) reveals the following two lemmas. Lemma 1. (i) (ii) (iii)

  19. (19) (20)

  20. Lemma 2. (i) (ii)

  21. Lemma 2. (21) (22)

  22. Marginal productivity of capital in the decentralized economy as (23) • The growth rate of the economy under the decentralized economy (24)

  23. The First-best optimal policies (25a) (25b)

  24. the government expenditure share (26a) the government revenue share (26b)

  25. Corollary 1. (i) (ii)

  26. Corollary 1. (iii) (iv)

  27. Comparison with Ott and Turnovsky (2006) If , then our model reduces to Ott and Turnovsky. • If , then the individual firm still over-estimate the MPK. Hence, an increase in or leads to an increase in the tax rate. • However, such a change will not affect the MPe if . • Eq. (16b) implies that the user fee should decrease.

  28. The Second-best optimal policies The fraction of government revenue allocated to excludable and non-excludable public inputs.

  29. Using these two definitions as well as market equilibrium conditions, eq. (18) implies that (27) Substituting eq. (27) in to eq.(20b) (20c)

  30. Substitute eq.(20c) into eq.(17), the growth rate is given as (28)

  31. Proposition 3. (Second-best optimal policies) The second-best optimal fractions of govern- ment revenue that are allocated to excludable and non-excludable public inputs are given as (29a) (29b)

  32. The second-best optimal tax rate and user fee are given as (29c) (29d)

  33. Under the second-best optimum (30a) and (30b)

  34. Corollary 2.The optimal tax rate under the second-best optimal is less than the output elasticity of public inputs, if the incentive effect of the user fee for the excludable public inputs is present.

  35. Literature • The second-best optimal tax rate is equal to the output elasticity of public inputs (Barro, 1990). • It is, however, generally felt that the optimal tax rate is not equal to the output elasticity of public inputs. (Chen, 2003; Hung, 2005; Ho and Wang, 2005) • With congestion, this optimal tax rate is independent of the degree of congestion (Glomm and Ravikumar, 1994). • With the presence of the incentive effect of user fees, the optimal tax rate is less than the output elasticity of public inputs.

  36. Corollary 3. (with the incentive effect) Eq. (28) (i) (ii)

  37. Corollary 3. (iii)

  38. User Fee and Expenditure on Excludable Public Inputs Total revenue generated by the user fee is sufficient to finance excludable public inputs if • Centralized economy • Decentralized economy

  39. Proposition 4. The revenue generated by the user fee alone is not sufficient to finance excludable public inputs under the first- and second-best optima.

  40. Conclusions • the optimal expenditure shares of non-exclud able and excludable public inputs are decided by their corresponding productive elasticity, regardless of the first- or second-best optimum. • an increase in the overall degree of congestion for excludable public inputs, on the one hand, always leads to an increase in the user fee and, on the other hand, leads to an increase in the first-best tax rate but a decrease in the second-best tax rate.

More Related