1 / 108

Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001)

Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001). Topic 3: Production and Costs. I. Introduction. We now begin to look behind the Supply Curve Recall: Supply curve tells us: Quantity sellers willing to supply at particular price per unit;

tejano
Télécharger la présentation

Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001)

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 3: Production and Costs

  2. I. Introduction • We now begin to look behind the Supply Curve • Recall: Supply curve tells us: • Quantity sellers willing to supply at particular price per unit; • Minimum price per unit sellers willing to sell particular quantity • Assumed to be upward sloping

  3. I. Introduction • We assume sellers are owner-managed firms (i.e. no agency issues) • Firms objective is to maximise profits • Thus, supply decision must reflect profit-maximising considerations • Thus to understand supply decision, we need to understand profit and profit maximisation

  4. Figure 1: Optimal Output q* Costs of Production Revenue ‘Optimal’ Output

  5. II. Profit • Profit = Total Revenue (TR) - Total Costs (TC) • Note the important distinction between Economic Profit and Accounting Profit • Opportunity Cost (OC) - amount lost by not using a particular resource in its next best alternative use. • Accountants ignore OC - only measure monetary costs

  6. II. Profit • Example: self-employed builder earns £10 and incurs £3 costs; his accounting profit is thus £7 • But if he had the alternative of working in MacDonalds for £8, then self-employment ‘costs’ him £1 per period. • Thus, it would irrational for him to continue working as a builder

  7. II. Profit • Formally, we define accounting profit as: • where TCa = totalaccountingcosts. We define economic profit as: • where TC = TCa + OC denotes total costs

  8. II. Profit • Thus: • Thus, economists include OC in their (stricter) definition of profits

  9. II. Profit • Define Normal (Economic) Profit • That is, where accounting profit just covers OC such that the firm is doing just as well as its next best alternative.

  10. II. Profit • Define Super-normal (Economic) Profit: • Supernormal profit thus provides true economic indicator of how well owners are doing by tying their money up in the business

  11. III. The Production Decision • Optimal (i.e. profit-maximising) q (i.e. q*) depends on marginal revenue (MR) and marginal cost (MC) • Define: MR = ΔTR / Δq MR = ΔTC / Δq • Decision to produce additional (i.e. marginal) unit of q (i.e. Δq = 1) depends on how this unit impacts upon firm’s total revenue and total costs

  12. III. The Production Decision • If additional unit of qcontributes more to TR than TC, then the firm increase production by one unit of q • If additional unit of qcontributes less to TR than TC, then the firm decreases production by one unit of q • Optimal (i.e. profit maximising) q (i.e. q*) is where additional unit ofq changesTR and TC by the same amount

  13. III. The Production Decision • Strategy: • MR > MC=>Increase q • MR < MC=>Decrease q • MR = MC=>Optimal q (i.e. q*) • Thus, two key factors: • Costs firm incurs in producing q • Revenue firm earns from producing q • We will look at each of these factors in turn.

  14. III. The Production Decision • Revenue affected by factors external to the firm. essentially, the environment within which it operates • Is it the only seller of a particular good, or is it one of many? Does it face a single rival? • We will explore the environments of perfect competition, monopoly and imperfect competition • But first, we explore costs

  15. IV. Costs • If the firm wishes to maximise profits, then it will also wish to minimise costs. • Two key factors determine costs of production: • Cost of productive inputs • Productive efficiency of firm • i.e. how much firm pays for its inputs; and the efficiency with which it transforms these inputs into outputs.

  16. IV. Costs • Formally, we envisage the firm as a production function: q = f(K, L) • Firm employs inputs of, e.g., capital (K) and labour (L) to produce output (q) • Assume cost per unit of capital is r and cost per unit of labour is w

  17. Figure 2: The Firm as a Production Function smoke r K q = f(K, L) L w Inputs Output

  18. IV. Costs • Assume for simplicity that the unit cost of inputs are exogenous to the firm • Thus, it can employ as many units of K and L it wishes at a constant price per unit • To be sure, if w = £5, then one unit of L would cost £5 and 6 units of L would cost £30 • Consider, then, productive efficiency

  19. V. Productive Efficiency • We describe efficiency of the firm’s productive relationship in two ways depending on the time scale involved: • Long Run: Period of time over which firm can change all of its factor inputs • Short Run: Period of time over which at least one of its factor is fixed. • We describe productive efficiency in: • Long Run: ‘Returns to Scale’ • Short Run: ‘Returns to a Factor’

  20. VI. Returns to Scale • Describes the effect on q when all inputs are changed proportionately • e.g. double (K, L); triple (K, L); increase (K, L), by factor of 1.7888452 • Does not matter how much we increase capital and labour as long as we increase them in the same proportion

  21. VI. Returns to Scale • Increasing Returns to Scale: Equi-proportionate increase in all inputs leads to a more than equi-proportionate increase in q • Decreasing Returns to Scale: Equi-proportionate increase in all inputs leads to a less than equi-proportionate increase in q • Constant Returns to Scale: Equi-proportionate increase in all inputs leads to same equi-proportionate increase in q

  22. VI. Returns to Scale • What causes changes in returns to scale? • Economies of Scale: Indivisibilities; specialisation; large Scale / better machinery • Diseconomies of Scale: Managerial diseconomies of Scale; geographical diseconomies • Balance of two forces is an empirical phenomenon (see Begg et al, pp. 111-113)

  23. VI. Returns to Scale • How do returns to scale relate to firm’s long run costs? • Efficiency with which firm can transform inputs into output in the long run will affect the cost of producing output in the long run • And this, will affect the shape of the firms long run total cost curve

  24. Figure 3: LTC & Constant Returns to Scale c LTC 15 10 5 q 0 10 20 30

  25. Figure 4: LTC & Decreasing Returns to Scale c LTC 25 12 5 q 0 10 20 30

  26. Figure 5: LTC & Increasing Returns to Scale c LTC 10 8 5 q 0 10 20 30

  27. VI. Returns to Scale • LTC tells firm much profit is being made given TR; but firm wants to know how much to produce for maximum profit. • For this it needs to know MR and MC • So can LTC tell us anything about LMC? • Yes!

  28. VI. Returns to Scale • Slope of line drawn tangent to LTC curve at particular level of q gives LMC of producing that level of q • i.e.

  29. Figure 6a: LTC & LMC c LTC x q 0 q0q1 Tan x = LTC / q

  30. Figure 6b: LTC & LMC c LTC x q 0 q0q1 Tan x = LTC / q

  31. Figure 6c: LTC & LMC c LTC x q 0 q0q1 Tan x = LTC / q

  32. Figure 6d: LTC & LMC c LTC x q 0 q0 Tan x = LMC(q0)

  33. Figure 6e: IRS Implies Decreasing LMC c LTC q 0 q0 q1

  34. Figure 7: IRS Implies Decreasing LMC c LMC q 0 q0 q1

  35. VI. Returns to Scale • Similarly, slope of line drawn from origin to point on LTC curve at particular level of q gives LAC of producing that level of q • i.e.

  36. Figure 8: LTC & LAC c LTC x q 0 q0 Tan x = LAC(q0)

  37. Figure 9: IRS Implies Decreasing LAC c LTC x z q 0 Tan x = LAC(q0)

  38. Figure 10: IRS Implies Decreasing LAC c LAC q 0 q0 q1

  39. VI. Returns to Scale • Generally, we will assume that firms first enjoy increasing returns to scale (IRS) and then decreasing returns to scale (DRS) • Thus, there is an implied ‘efficient’ size of a firm • i.e. when it has exhausted all its IRS • qmes - ‘minimum efficient scale’

  40. Figure 11: IRS and then DRS c LTC q 0 qmes

  41. VI. Returns to Scale • Note the relationship between LMC and LAC: q < qmes LMC < LAC q = qmes LMC = LAC q > qmes LMC > LAC

  42. Figure 12a: IRS and then DRS c LTC LMC < LAC q 0

  43. Figure 12b: IRS and then DRS c LTC LAC =LMC LMC < LAC q 0

  44. Figure 12c: IRS and then DRS c LTC LMC > LAC LAC =LMC LMC < LAC q 0

  45. Figure 12d: IRS and then DRS c LTC LMC > LAC LAC =LMC LAC > LMC q 0 qmes

  46. VI. Returns to Scale • Thus: LAC is falling if: LMC < LAC LAC is flat if: LMC = LAC LAC is rising if: LMC > LAC

  47. Figure 13: IRS Implies Decreasing LAC c LTC 0 q LMC LAC q 0 qmes

  48. VII. Returns to a Factor • Returns to a factor describe productive efficiency in the short run when at least one factor is fixed • Usually assumed to be capital • Short-run production function:

  49. VII. Returns to a Factor • Increasing Returns to a Factor: Increase in variable factor leads to a more than proportionate increase in q • Decreasing Returns to a Factor: Increase in variable factor leads to a less than proportionate increase in q • Constant Returns to a Factor: Increase in variable factor leads to same proportionate increase in q

  50. Figure 14: Returns to a Factor q IRF CRF DRF L 0 Short-Run Production Function:

More Related