1 / 49

UNIT IV: INFORMATION & WELFARE

UNIT IV: INFORMATION & WELFARE. Decision under Uncertainty Bargaining Games Externalities & Public Goods Review. 12/12. Decision under Uncertainty.

Télécharger la présentation

UNIT IV: INFORMATION & WELFARE

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. UNIT IV: INFORMATION & WELFARE • Decision under Uncertainty • Bargaining Games • Externalities & Public Goods • Review 12/12

  2. Decision under Uncertainty In UNIT I we assumed that consumers have perfect information about the possible options they face (their income and prices); and about the utility consequences of their choices (their preferences). Now, we will ask whether our model can be extended to deal with more realistic cases in which decisions are made without perfect information. We will also ask how imperfect (asymmetric) information affects market outcomes.

  3. Decision under Uncertainty The Economics of Information: How can I maximize utility given incomplete info? How much info should I gather? We can distinguish between 2 sources of uncertainty: • The behavior of other actors (strategic uncertainty) • states of nature (natural uncertainty) • Will it rain? Or not? • Is there oil in the drilling hole? • Will the roulette wheel come up red? (1 -- 35) • Is the car a lemon?

  4. Decision under Uncertainty The Economics of Information: How can I maximize utility given incomplete info? How much info should I gather? We can distinguish between 2 sources of uncertainty: • states of nature (natural uncertainty) • Will it rain? Or not? • Is there oil in the drilling hole? • Will the roulette wheel come up red? (1 -- 35) • Is the car a lemon?

  5. Decision under Uncertainty • Expected Value v. Expected Utility • Risk Preferences • Reducing Risk: Insurance • Contingent Consumption • Adverse Selection (and Moral Hazard)

  6. Expected Value & Expected Utility Which would you prefer? A) 50-50 chance of winning $30,000 or losing $5,000 B) Sure thing of $10,000 How much would you be willing to pay for the chance to win $2n if the head comes up on nth flip? 2(1/2) + 4(1/4) + … = 1 + 1 + … =

  7. Expected Value & Expected Utility How much would you be willing to pay for the chance to win $2n if a heads comes up on nth flip? Expected Value (EV): the sum of the value (V) of each possible state, weighted by the probability (p) of that state occurring. On 1 flip: p(H) = ½ (2) + 4(1/4) + … = 1 + 1 + … =

  8. Expected Value & Expected Utility How much would you be willing to pay for the chance to win $2n if a heads comes up on nth flip? Expected Value (EV): the sum of the value (V) of each possible state, weighted by the probability (p) of that state occurring. On 1 flip: EV = p(V)H = (½)2 + 4(1/4) + … = 1 + 1 + … =

  9. Expected Value & Expected Utility How much would you be willing to pay for the chance to win $2n if a heads comes up on nth flip? Expected Value (EV): the sum of the value (V) of each possible state, weighted by the probability (p) of that state occurring. On nth flip: EV(Hn) = ½n(2n) + 4(1/4) + … = 1 + 1 + … =

  10. Expected Value & Expected Utility How much would you be willing to pay for the chance to win $2n if a heads comes up on nth flip? Expected Value (EV): the sum of the value (V) of each possible state, weighted by the probability (p) of that state occurring. On nth flip: EV(Hn) = ½n(2n) + 4(1/4) + … = 1 + 1 + … = EV(H)=½(2)+(1/4)4+(1/8)8 H T Flip 1: Win $2 ½ ½ H T Flip 2: Win $4 ¼ ¼ H T Flip 3: Win $8 ½ ¼ 8 8

  11. Expected Value & Expected Utility How much would you be willing to pay for the chance to win $2n if a heads comes up on nth flip? Expected Value (EV): the sum of the value (V) of each possible state, weighted by the probability (p) of that state occurring. On n flips: EV(H)=(½)2+(1/4)4+(1/8)8+…=1+1+1+…= infinity So, you’d be willing to pay an awful lot? What’s going on here?

  12. Expected Value & Expected Utility With examples such as these, David Bernoulli (1738) observed that rational agents often behave contrary to expected value maximization. Instead, they maximize: Expected Utility (EU): the sum of the utility of each possible state, weighted by the probability of that state occurring. EU = p1(U(s1)) + p2(U(s2)) + … pn(U(sn)) Where p is the probability of that state occurring. arise because utility will be a non-linear function of “wealth”.

  13. Expected Value & Expected Utility With examples such as these, David Bernoulli (1738) observed that rational agents often behave contrary to expected value maximization. Instead, they maximize: Expected Utility (EU): the sum of the utility of each possible state, weighted by the probability of that state occurring. Rankings of expected values and expected utilities need not be the same! Differences arise because utility will be a non-linear function of “wealth” and will depend on endowments. * * or “income” or “consumption”

  14. Expected Value & Expected Utility Diminishing Marginal Utility: The intrinsic worth of wealth increases with wealth, but at a diminishing rate. U U(15) U(10) U(5) von Neumann-Morgenstern Utility Indexes MU = ½W-½ U = W½ MU = 1/W U = lnW For 2 states: EU = p(U(Wi)) + (1-p)(U(Wj)) MRS = (p/(1-p))MUi/MUj 5 10 15 W

  15. Risk Preferences A risk averse consumer will prefer a certain income to a risky income with the same expected value. U U(15) U(10) U(5) The chord represents the chance to win $5 or $15. .5U(5) +.5U(15) 5 CE 10 15 W

  16. Risk Preferences A risk averse consumer will prefer a certain income to a risky income with the same expected value. U U(15) U(10) U(5) Certainty Equivalent (CE) of an equal chance of winning $5 and $15 Risk Premium = 10 – CE .5U(5) +.5U(15) 5 CE 10 15 W

  17. Risk Preferences A risk loving consumer will prefer a risky income to a certain income with the same expected value. U U(15) .5U(5) +.5U(15) U(5) U(10) 5 CE 10 15 W

  18. Risk Preferences A risk neutral consumer is indifferent between a risky income and a certain income with the same expected value. U U(15) U(10) U(5) 5 CE 10 15 W

  19. Risk Preferences A risk neutral consumer is indifferent between a risky income and a certain income with the same expected value. Do any of these cases violate any of our assumptions about well-behaved preferences? Draw a set of indifference curves for each case. U U(15) U(10) U(5) 5 CE 10 15 W

  20. Risk and Insurance A risk averse consumer will prefer a certain income to a risky income with the same expected value. Given the opportunity, therefore, she will attempt to smooth the variability of her wealth, by spreading (or diversifying) her risks across states. Insurance offers a way to buy wealth in the event of a low wealth (or “bad”) state, by transferring some wealthfrom the “good” to the “bad” state.

  21. Risk and Insurance A risk averse consumer has wealth of $35,000, including a car worth $10,000. There is a 1/100 chance that the car will be stolen. So there is a 0.01 chance his wealth will be $25,000 and a 0.99 chance it will be $35,000. EW = 0.01(25000) + 0.99(35000) Buying insurance can change this distribution.

  22. Risk and Insurance If his car is stolen, his wealth will be $25,000; if it is not stolen, his wealth will be $35,000. Buying insurance is transferring wealth from the “good” to the “bad” state. Wg $35,000 Suppose he can by $1000 insurance at a premium of $1/100. g = .01 How much insurance will he buy?he buy? (35,000 – 10) $25,000 Wb (25,000 + 1000 -10) Not to scale

  23. Risk and Insurance If his car is stolen, his wealth will be $25,000; if it is not stolen, his wealth will be $35,000. Buying insurance is transferring wealth from the “good” to the “bad” state. Wg $35,000 Suppose he can by $1000 insurance at a premium of $1/100. g = .01 How much insurance will he buy?he buy? ? $25,000 Wb

  24. Risk and Insurance If his car is stolen, his wealth will be $25,000; if it is not stolen, his wealth will be $35,000. Buying insurance is transferring wealth from the “good” to the “bad” state. Wg $35,000 Given the chance to buy insurance at an “actuarily fair” price (i.e., g = p), a risk averse consumer will fully insure. Equalizing wealth across states. he buy? Certainty Line 34,900 $25,000 Wb 34,900

  25. Risk and Insurance Insurance is a way to allocate wealth across possible states of the world. In essence, he is purchasing contingent claims on consumption (wealth) in the two states. So we can solve in the usual way: Wg Eg Endowment More generally: E =Endowment K = dollars of insurance g = premium ? Eg - gK Eb Wb Eb + K - gK

  26. Contingent Consumption If his car is stolen, his wealth will be $25,000; if it is not stolen, his wealth will be $35,000. Buying insurance is transferring wealth from the “good” to the “bad” state. Wg $35,000 Endowment Now suppose the premium rises to $1.10/100 (g = .011). His vN-M Index: U = lnW How much insurance will he buy? 35000 - gk $25,000 Wb 25,000 + K - gK

  27. Contingent Consumption If his car is stolen, his wealth will be $25,000; if it is not stolen, his wealth will be $35,000. Buying insurance is transferring wealth from the “good” to the “bad” state. Wg $35,000 Slope(m) = DWg/DWb = -gK/(K-gK) = -g/(1-g) g = Pb 1-g = Pg m = -Pb/Pg $25,000 Wb Not to scale

  28. Contingent Consumption If his car is stolen, his wealth will be $25,000; if it is not stolen, his wealth will be $35,000. Buying insurance is transferring wealth from the “good” to the “bad” state. Wg $35,000 Budget Constraint: Wg = m(Wb) + Wg(int) Wg = -(.011/.989)Wb + 34722 Wg* m = -.0111 $25,000 Wb Wb* Not to scale

  29. Contingent Consumption If his car is stolen, his wealth will be $25,000; if it is not stolen, his wealth will be $35,000. Buying insurance is transferring wealth from the “good” to the “bad” state. Wg $35,000 U = lnW EU = p(U(Wb)) + (1-p)(U(Wg)) MRS = (p/(1-p))MUb/MUg = (.01/.99)(Wg/Wb) = P(Wb)/P(Wg) = g/(1-g) Wg* $25,000 Wb Wb* Not to scale

  30. Contingent Consumption If his can is stolen, his wealth will be $25,000; if it is not stolen, his wealth will be $35,000. Buying insurance is transferring wealth from the “good” to the “bad” state. Wg $35,000 MRS = (.01/.99)(Wg/Wb) Pb/Pg = g/(1-g) MRS = Pb/Pg => Wb = .909Wg Wg = -(.011/.989)Wb + 34722 Wg = $ 35077 Wg* $25,000 Wb Wb* Not to scale

  31. Contingent Consumption If his can is stolen, his wealth will be $25,000; if it is not stolen, his wealth will be $35,000. Buying insurance is transferring wealth from the “good” to the “bad” state. Wg $35,000 Wg = $ 34925 So he pays $75 for $6818 of ins Wg*=34925 $25,000 Wb Wb*=31743 Not to scale

  32. Contingent Consumption How would the answer change for a risk lover? Wg Eg A risk lover will maximize utility (reach her highest indifference curve) in a corner solution. In this case, remaining at the endowment. Eb Wb

  33. Adverse Selection Consider the market for drivers insurance: “Good” drivers have accidents with prob = 0.2 “Bad” = 0.8 Good and bad drivers are equally distributed in population. At the actuarially fair price of $0.50/$1 coverage: • for good drivers price is too high -> don’t insure • for bad too low -> insure Bad drivers are “selected in”; good are “selected out” What price would an actuarially fair insurance company charge?

  34. Adverse Selection Consider the market for drivers insurance: “Good” drivers have accidents with prob = 0.2 “Bad” = 0.8 Good and bad drivers are equally distributed in population. At the actuarially fair price of $0.50/$1 coverage: • for good drivers price is too high -> don’t insure • for bad too low -> insure Bad drivers are “selected in”; good are “selected out” Driver quality is a hidden characteristic

  35. Adverse Selection Consider the market for drivers insurance: “Good” drivers have accidents with prob = 0.2 “Bad” = 0.8 Good and bad drivers are equally distributed in population. At the actuarially fair price of $0.50/$1 coverage: • for good drivers price is too high -> don’t insure • for bad too low -> insure Bad drivers are “selected in”; good are “selected out” Asymmetric Information

  36. Acquiring a Company BUYER represents Company A (the Acquirer), which is currently considering make a tender offer to acquire Company T (the Target) from SELLER. BUYER and SELLER are going to be meeting to negotiate a price. Company T is privately held, so its true value is known only to SELLER. Whatever the value, Company T is worth 50% more in the hands of the acquiring company, due to improved management and corporate synergies. BUYER only knows that its value is somewhere between 0 and 100 ($/share), with all values equally likely. Source: M. Bazerman

  37. Acquiring a Company What offer should Buyer make?

  38. Acquiring a Company 45 123 BU MBA Students Source: Bazerman, 1992 27 18 9 7 4 5 4 1 0 $0 10-15 20-25 30-35 40-45 50-55 60-65 70-75 80-85 90-95 Offers

  39. Acquiring a Company 45 123 BU MBA Students Similar results from MIT Master’s Candidates CPA; CEOs. Source: Bazerman, 1992 27 18 9 7 4 5 4 1 0 $0 10-15 20-25 30-35 40-45 50-55 60-65 70-75 80-85 90-95 Offers

  40. Acquiring a Company OFFER VALUE ACCEPT OR VALUE GAIN OR TO SELLER REJECT TO BUYER LOSS (O) (s) (3/2 s = b) (b - O) $60 $0 A $0 $-60 10 A 15 -45 20 A 30 -30 30 A 45 -15 40 A 60 0 50 A 75 15 60 R - - 70 R - -

  41. Acquiring a Company The key to the problem is the asymmetric information structure of the game. SELLER knows the true value of the company (s). BUYER knows only the upper and lower limits (0 < s < 100). Therefore, buyer must form an expectation on s (s'). BUYER also knows that the company is worth 50% more under the new management, i.e., b' = 3/2 s'. BUYER makes an offer (O). The expected payoff of the offer, EP(O), is the difference between the offer and the expected value of the company in the hands of BUYER: EP(O) = b‘ – O = 3/2s‘ – O.

  42. Acquiring a Company BUYER wants to maximize her payoff by offering the smallest amount (O) she expects will be accepted: EP(O) = b‘ – O = 3/2s‘ – O. O = s' + e. Seller accepts if O > s. Now consider this: Buyer has formed her expectation based on very little information. If Buyer offers O and Seller accepts, this considerably increases Buyer’s information, so she can now update her expectation on s. How should Buyer update her expectation, conditioned on the new information that s < O?

  43. Acquiring a Company BUYER wants to maximize her payoff by offering the smallest amount (O) she expects will be accepted: EP(O) = b‘ – O = 3/2s‘ – O. O = s' + e. Seller accepts if O > s. Let’s say BUYER offers $50. If SELLER accepts, BUYER knows that s cannot be greater than (or equal to) 50, that is: 0 < s < 50. Since all values are equally likely, s''/(s < O) = 25. The expected value of the company to BUYER (b'' = 3/2s'' = 37.50), which is less than the 50 she just offered to pay. (EP(O) = - 12.5.) When SELLER accepts, BUYER gets a sinking feeling in the pit of her stomach. THE WINNER’S CURSE!

  44. Acquiring a Company BUYER wants to maximize her payoff by offering the smallest amount (O) she expects will be accepted: EP(O) = b‘ – O = 3/2s‘ – O. O = s' + e. Seller accepts if O > s. Generally: EP(O) = O - ¼s' (-e). EP is negative for all values of O. THE WINNER’S CURSE!

  45. Acquiring a Company • The high level of uncertainty swamps the potential gains available, such that value is often left on the table, i.e., on average the outcome is inefficient. • Under these particular conditions, BUYER should not make an offer. • SELLER has an incentive to reveal some information to BUYER, because if BUYER can reduce the uncertainty, she may make an offer that leaves both players better off.

  46. Adverse Selection • Lemons (Akerlof 1970): Buyers of used cars can’t distinguish between high and low quality cars (lemons); the price of used cars reflects this uncertainty; and the price is lower than high quality cars are worth. Thus owners of high quality cars won’t choose to sell their cars at the market price; eventually, only (mostly) lemons will be sold on the used car market. • Sellers of high-quality products can use means to certify their value: Appraisals; audits; “reputable” agents; brand names.

  47. Moral Hazard • Buying insurance may make drivers take more risks. Measures to prevent damage or theft are costly, so drivers may decide to avoid these costs, e.g., “why lock the car, if I’m insured against theft?” • If insurance companies cannot monitor driver’s habits, they will respond by charging higher prices to all, so good drivers leave the market … . • The result is an inefficient allocation of insurance and a net loss to society, b/c the price of insurance does not reflect the true social cost.

  48. Next Time 12/19 We’ll put together “natural”& “strategic” uncertainty and study bargaining games.

  49. Next Time 12/19 Bargaining Pindyck & Rubenfeld, Ch. 17. Besanko, Ch. 15. Externalities and Public Goods Pindyck and Rubenfeld, Ch 18. Besanko, Ch. 17.

More Related