1 / 63

Sector-Specific Technical Change: Mapping Empirical Measurement and Stylized Models

This research paper explores the measurement of sector-specific technology shocks using empirical data and maps them into stylized models. It discusses conceptual issues, manipulates input-output tables, and presents empirical results based on KLEM productivity data.

dmanchester
Télécharger la présentation

Sector-Specific Technical Change: Mapping Empirical Measurement and Stylized Models

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Sector-Specific Technical Change John Fernald Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Miles Kimball University of Michigan and NBER Susanto Basu Boston College and NBER Jonas Fisher Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

  2. Motivation: What causes business cycles? Comovement: Candidate shocks must change Y, H, C, I in same direction Technology shocks can do this in simple models But in data, technology improvements often found to raise Y, C but reduce hours [Gali (1999), Basu, Fernald, Kimball (2006)] Francis and Ramey (2005): “The original technology-driven … business cycle hypothesis does appear to be dead.” Can we resuscitate technology shocks as major drivers of cycles? …while explaining the original negative evidence of Gali, BFK, et al? Yes…by reconsidering what an “aggregate” shock is Greenwood, Hercowitz, and Krusell and literature that followed (e.g., Fisher) emphasize final-use sector

  3. We empirically measure technology by final-use sector: Consumption versus Equipment Investment A new empirical method to identify sector-specific shocks Idea: Estimate technology residuals from industry data, then aggregate through the input-output tables Contribution: We do not identify final-use technology from rel. price data Robust to time-varying markups, sticky prices, variable factor utilization, increasing returns, differing factor shares, changing tax rates, … Consumption- and investment-sector shocks individually have economic effects with right comovement properties Investment technology improvements are sharply contractionary, whereas consumption technology improvements are expansionary Prior empirical literature mostly considers the average of these shocks, which does not have the right comovement properties Relative prices respond very slowly to relative technology shocks Discuss what models might be consistent with the estimated effects

  4. Outline Motivation Conceptual issues in empirical measurement Mapping simple dynamic model to complicated world Manipulating input-output (I-O) tables Data and empirical results Two stylized models Conclusion

  5. A general two-sector production structure Production functions for consumption, C, and investment, J: • Production structure could be embedded in many DSGE models • Want empirical estimates of ZCand ZJ using assumptions consistent with large class of models

  6. Note: Production structure is benchmark Greenwood-Hercowitz-Krusell, with different normalization of shocks We have separate technologies for the two sectors: Investment-specific technical change literature normalizes differently:

  7. How to measure ZC and ZJ? Existing method pioneered by Greenwood, Hercowitz, and Krusell • Use relative price of cons. to equip. to infer relative technology of equipment to consumption 7

  8. Our method: Estimate final-use technology “directly” without using relative prices • Problem: 2-sector production model is simple, but data are complicated and messy • Many firms/sectors, that sell to one another. • Conceptually, consider stream of production leading to a final consumption/investment good, e.g., Ci • Function of the capital, labor, and technology used in entire stream • But we don’t observe the K and L needed to produce each final output • Use input-output tables to infer needed K, L and hence implied final-goods technology

  9. Using input-output tables to map disaggregated technology shocks into final-use technology • Direct technology estimates from industry production functions • vector dz of (gross-output) technology shocks, [dz1 , dz2, …]’ • Implicit production function for delivering output to final consumption or investment. Intuition: • Matrix B is (nominal) intermediate input shares • bij is share of commodity j in producing commodity i • Technology for deliveries to final demand • Weight by final-use shares, e.g.:

  10. Given TFP for final-use commodities, ZC, ZJ, etc. easy 11

  11. What is “net exports technology” • In data, have to confront that economy is open • Some commodity supply is imported • Purpose of exports is to import (allowing use of those commodities) • “Technology”: Terms of trade • Final-use net-exports technology captures ability to obtain imports from exports • Terms of trade improvements • Technology improvements in goods we export

  12. Outline Motivation Conceptual issues in empirical measurement Mapping simple dynamic model to complicated world Manipulating input-output (I-O) tables Data and empirical results Two stylized models Conclusion

  13. Start with KLEM productivity data from Jorgenson et al. • Key collaborators include Fraumeni, Ho, Stiroh, Gollop, and others • Annual input-output tables underlying these productivity data • 1960-2005 • 35 industries/commodities • Includes final use, which allows us to distinguish • ND-S Consumption (don’t have owner-occ housing) • Consumer Durables • Government purchases of G&S (not govt administration) • Equipment investment • Structures investment • Exports and Imports 14

  14. We modify original data to incorporate alternative deflators for durable goods Key work of Gordon (1983), updated by Cummins-Violante (2002) New deflators redefine output for each industry Aggregate using I-O tables to get new measures of C, I, etc. Of course, also new prices for each category of expenditure

  15. Need vector of industry technology innovations • Production function • Could use industry Solow residuals: • Concerns: • Non-constant returns • unobserved variations in labor effort Ei and capital’s workweek Si

  16. We estimate industry technology residuals dzifollowing Basu-Fernald-Kimball (2006, AER) • Regress industry output growth dyion input growth dxi and hours-per worker growth dhi: • Use updated Ramey-Hall instruments: • Hamilton-style oil-price increases, • government defense spending, • monetary innovations from an SVAR • “Corrected” technology dzi = (ci+εi) controls for factor utilization and non-constant RTS • For agriculture, mining, and govt enterpirises, where BFK don’t estimate residuals, we use uncorrected TFP • Also use an unadjusted terms of trade 17

  17. Feeding industry BFK shocks through I-O tables: Equip and con. dur. technology rise fastest Cumulated log change in final-use BFK technology 18

  18. Relative sectoral technology diverges from typical macro proxy of relative prices Correlation of growth in relative TFP, relative BFK technology, and relative output prices • Relative price changes have correlation (in annual data) of only 0.23 with relative BFK technology 20

  19. Equipment investment technology and consumption technology have very different macroeconomic effects • Each row is a separate regression of log change in variable shown on current and lagged tech shocks • Equip tech. includes con dur and govt equip. Cons. (Nondur) tech includes structures and nonequip. govt. • Intrumental variables estimation. Instruments zero out terms of trade and industry shocks not estimated via BFK. Annual data 1961-2005. 22

  20. Technology shocks explain a lot of the variation in equipment… Corr = 0.59

  21. …as well as hours Corr = 0.64

  22. Why are investment technology improvements contractionary—even for investment? Relative price of I drops very slowly in response to relative technology improvement Creates strong incentive to delay purchases Durable goods have high intertemporal elasticities of substitution Demand for durables declines as a result

  23. In long run, relative prices (CNDS to equip/condurables) move with relative TFP and relative technology 28

  24. Relative prices respond to relative technology with long lags • Relative Price (LHS var): growth in price of consumption (ND and services) relative to price of equipment • Rel. Technology (RHS var) : Growth in equipment technology relative to consumption (ND and services) 29

  25. Outline Motivation Conceptual issues in empirical measurement Mapping simple dynamic model to complicated world Manipulating input-output (I-O) tables Data and empirical results Two stylized models Conclusion 31

  26. What models might match these facts? Our work uncovers two technology shocks that move output, hours, consumption and investment in the same direction To get output and other variables to increase, we need: a positive consumption technology shock or a negative equipment technology shock!

  27. In benchmark RBC model, consumption-specific technology shocks have no dynamic effects Suppose period utility is logarithmic U = ln(C) + v(1-L) Let A be multiplicative technology that affects only production of non-durable consumption Consumption-technology neutrality proposition: In two-sector RBC model, stochastic process for A does not affect labor hours L, investment J, or the quantity of resources devoted to producing consumption goods (X) A enters separably in the utility function, so it doesn’t affect decision rules 33

  28. Comments More general King-Plosser-Rebelo preferences: If A follows a geometric random walk it has no effect on optimal decision rules for L, X and J. Shocks to investment technology should have standard RBC effects We find neither consumption technology neutrality nor expansionary effects of investment technology improvements We may have resuscitated technology-driven business cycles, but not real business cycles! 36

  29. Simple 2-Sector Sticky-Price Model Period utility is: Dixit-Stiglitz preference for variety, implying markup of 1..1 Cobb-Douglas production functions for C and I Same fixed cost of production (10 percent of st. st. output) Same factor shares (a = 0.3) Factors mobile across sectors Calvo-pricing : Probability θC = θJ =0.75 of keeping unchanged price Monetary policy follows Taylor rule, where Fed targets the “marginal cost gap” and consumer inflation 37

  30. Response to investment technology improvement labor

  31. Response to consumption technology improvement labor

  32. Conclusions • Theory suggests that “final use” sector where technology change occurs matters for its effects • E.g., consumption-technology neutrality, 2-sector sticky-price model • Measure sectoral technical change using a new method that doesn’t require relative prices • Effects of sector-specific technology shocks look like business cycles • Equipment technology improvements reduce output, hours, investment, and consumption • Consumption technology improvement raise output, hours, investment, and consumption • Need to think about models that might explain these findings • Multi-sector sticky-price models appear to have some promise 40

  33. 41

  34. Empirical Implications: Low EIS and Permanent Tech Shocks • With permanent technology shocks and King-Plosser-Rebelo utility and relatively low elasticity of intertemporal substitution (≈ 0.3), investment technology shocks also have very little immediate effects on labor hours, though they do raise investment in a way that consumption technology shocks do not. 42

  35. 43

  36. Comments • With log preferences, ln(A) is additively-separable: • Any stochastic process for A has no effect on optimal decision rules for N, X and I. • More general King-Plosser-Rebelo preferences: • If A follows a geometric random walk it has no effect on optimal decision rules for N, X and I. 44

  37. What is “technology”? • Is ‘technology’ the economy’s PPF? • The change in production functions for domestic C and I? • We use the first, broader, definition. 45

  38. Notes • Trade technology is the terms of trade • Suppose there are no intermediate-inputs and one of each final-use commodity (e.g., a single consumption good) • Final-use technology is technology in that commodity • Our definition is correct for typical two-sector macro model • Otherwise, takes account of intermediate-input flows • If all sectors face same input prices and have identical factor shares (including intermediates), then relative final-goods prices reflect relative technologies • Again, our definition is correct for typical special cases used in macro (e.g., Greenwood, Hercowitz, Krusell) 46

  39. We aggregate commodity technology shocks to final uses with constant-share aggregation 48

  40. Motivation: In benchmark RBC model, consumption-technology shocks are neutral • Suppose utility is logarithmic U = ln(C) – v(L) • Let A be multiplicative technology for producing non-durable consumption • Consumption-technology neutrality proposition: • In two-sector RBC model, stochastic process for A does not affect labor hours L, investment J, or the quantity of resources devoted to producing consumption goods (X) • A affects only production of nondurable consumption goods 49

  41. Social-planner’s problem for two-sector growth model, with CRS, identical production technologies 50

  42. This is special case of following problem, where Atis additively separable, and thus doesn’t affect decision rules 51

  43. Equivalent problem: This is special case of following problem, where Atis additively separable, and thus doesn’t affect decision rules Empirically, do shocks to different final sectors have different economic effects? 52

  44. What we do instead Seek a more robust way to measure relative technology Use industry data to estimate underlying shocks Production-function regressions a la BFK (2006) Then aggregate using I-O tables to final-use technology changes for C, I, etc. Present findings, implications for business-cycle models

  45. Outline Introduction: Declining relative price of equipment Motivation: Consumption-technology neutrality Conceptual issues in empirical measurement Mapping simple dynamic model to complicated world Terms of trade as a form of technology Manipulating input-output (I-O) tables Data and empirical results: Bottom-up v. top-down Interpretation 55

  46. Motivation: In benchmark RBC model, consumption-specific technology shocks have no dynamic effects Suppose period utility is logarithmic U = ln(C) + v(1-L) Let A be multiplicative technology that affects only production of non-durable consumption 56

  47. Note: This model is benchmark Greenwood-Hercowitz-Krusell model, with a different normalization of the two shocks We normalized on: Investment-specific technical change literature normalizes differently: 57

  48. We interpret terms of trade as a form of technology In closed economy, by definition, only domestic factors affect ability to convert consumption goods to investment goods In open economy, foreign technology or demand might affect ability to obtain consumption/investment with unchanged labor and investment Purpose of exports is to import trade is a special (linear) technology, with terms-of-trade changes as technology shocks 58

  49. Two issues arise in input-output data to measure relevant intermediate-input matrix B Final use is by commodity, productivity data (dzi) are by industry I-O make table maps commodity production to industries Final-use is from total commodity supply, not domestic production I-O use table tells us both production and imports 59

  50. What does an input-output use table look like? Columns give inputs into domestic production Rows give “uses” of the commodity Nominal commodity-by-commodity use table 60

More Related