1 / 23

Improving firm productivity: Policy and business factors

Improving firm productivity: Policy and business factors. Jagadeesh Sivadasan University of Michigan. BRAC-IGC-IIG Conference on Entrepreneurship and Development: Policies, Practices and Experience March 27-28, Dhaka. Productivity and GDP.

hung
Télécharger la présentation

Improving firm productivity: Policy and business factors

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Improving firm productivity: Policy and business factors Jagadeesh Sivadasan University of Michigan BRAC-IGC-IIG Conference on Entrepreneurship and Development: Policies, Practices and ExperienceMarch 27-28, Dhaka

  2. Productivity and GDP • Early work by Solow (1957) and Denison (1962, 1967) found that per capita capital accumulation accounted for less than 25% of per capita GDP growth; productivity (TFP) growth accounted for more than 50% • Young (1995) argued that factor accumulation (capital + education) key to East Asian growth miracle; later work by Klenow and Rodriguez-Clare (1997) suggests a very strong role for TFP in most of these countries as well • Easterly and Levine (2001) review concluded that TFP plays a prominent role in explaining growth across the world • Understanding micro-economic underpinnings of country-level TFP important then for promoting growth • At the micro-level, incredible variation in TFP across firms • In the US 90th percentile plant produces 2 times as much output as the 10th percentile plant (for same level of inputs) (Syverson 2004) • In China and India, this ratio is 5:1 (Hseih and Klenow, 2009)

  3. Outline of Presentation • My paper on 1991 Indian policy reforms and plant productivity • Background on reforms • Theoretical framework • Data • Empirical results • Summary of recent related work on economic policies/trade liberalization and productivity • Summary of recent work on business practices and productivity

  4. Background on 1991 reforms • Liberalization in 1991 on all three policy fronts • Industrial policy • License requirements almost completely abolished • Foreign investment (FDI) regulations • FDI upto 51% allowed in a number of targeted sectors • Trade policy (tariff/non-tariff barriers) • Tariff rates reduced, with larger cuts for some sectors\ • All of these essentially reduced barriers to competition • My empirical paper focuses on 2 and 3 • Because these were differentially targeted at certain industries, easier to assess effects

  5. Competition & Productivity – Reasons for productivity improvements • More competitive markets leads to higher productivity: • More innovation [Arrow 1962 etc] • Less slack [Hicks 1935 etc] • Encouraging adoption of technology [Rodrik 1992 etc] • Less resources wasted on rent-seeking [Posner 1975 etc] • Barriers to entry also barriers to adoption of new methods/technology -- allows insiders/incumbents to (e.g. Parente and Prescott 2002) • Reallocation to more productive firms [Hopenhayn 1992, Melitz 2003 etc] • Trade specifically • Learning from foreign investors/competitors • Technology embodied in inputs

  6. Arguments for protection • Protection was motivated by following arguments: • Better incentives for innovation [Schumpeter 1942, etc] • Encouraging adoption of technology [Aghion & Howitt 1992, etc] • Less slack [Horn, Lang, and Lundgren 1994, etc] • External scale economies at national level [Helpman & Krugman, 1985] • High learning rates and spillover [Grossman & Helpman 1991, etc

  7. Motivation for reforms • Reforms triggered by BOP crisis, in turn caused by • Collapse of Soviet Union (India’s key trade partner) • First Gulf war (which impacted inward remittances) • But also motivated by realization by mid-80s that new policies required: • Export-focused countries had grown faster: e.g. Korea, Taiwan • Failure of Soviet model • Indian industry clearly uncompetitive: e.g. Indian cars still mostly 1950s models

  8. Description of data • Dataset based on annual survey of plants – similar to the LRD in the US • Repeated cross-section of about 40,000 plants (see table 1), 1986-87 to 1994-95, covers entire manufacturing sector • A census sector of about 22,000 larger plants surveyed every year, all other firms randomly sampled at approximately 1/3rd every year • Some data issues (mitigated by diff-in-diff approach): • Possible under-reporting of value added (for tax purposes) and workers (for labor law reasons) • Large informal sector not covered by the surveys

  9. Methodology • In first step estimate TFP • adopt a method that addressing some endogeneity concerns typical in TFP measurement • check robustness to using a range of measures • Next, we regress estimated TFP on dummies for reforms • Because reforms introduced in 1991 targeting specific industries • use time and industry fixed effects, to estimate Difference-in-differences effects on plant-level TFP • this controls for contemporaneous macro-shocks • We also do some further explorations of the results, looking at: • contributions of plant and reallocation terms to aggregate productivity change • whether TFP changes linked to changes in measures of competition • check for heterogeneous effects across industries/regions

  10. Summary graph: large relative improvements of productivity in reformed sectors

  11. Effects of FDI and Tariff Reform on TFP

  12. Robustness checks • Robust to using seven other productivity measures • Robust to using alternative measures of Tariff liberalization (including continuous measure of tariff changes) • Robust to including a number of period-specific industry controls • Pre-91 productivity growth • Export intensity • Capital intensity • Distance to frontier • Robust to excluding new entrants – so improvements are to older/existing plants • Robust to controlling for de-licensing of some sectors

  13. Aggregate output growth decomposition • FDI reformed industries: most output growth from intra-plant TFP growth • Tariff reformed industries: equal share of input growth, inter-industry reallocation and intra-plant TFP growth • Not much role for intra-industry reallocation

  14. TFP growth across the distribution • Consistent with prominent role for within-plant changes, we find shift in productivity across the full distribution • Improvement at top quartiles suggest there was slack/inefficiency even at productive firms, not just at the bottom of the distribution

  15. Role of competition • The pattern here is consistent with competition leading to TFP growth • output price declined, consistent with higher competitive intensity • the output price declines NOT from pass-through of input price declines • TFP growth offsets the competitive pressure, so no net margin declines • consistent with increased competition, herfindahl index and concentration ratios fell

  16. Which regions/industries show greater improvements • Some evidence that employer friendly states (per Besley and Burgess 2002) saw greater improvements • No/ weak effect for financial development/coastal status • Some weak evidence that industries closer to the frontier fared better • Some evidence that privately-owned plants fared better than government owned • No/weak effect for export orientation/capital intensity

  17. Other recent work on trade/industrial policy • Industrial policy • Aghion, Burgess, Redding and Zilibotti (2008) examined effect of de-licensing • Find much stronger firm growth in employer-friendly states • Trade liberalization • ShanthiNataraj (2009) looked at effect of tariff reductions on a larger sample that includes informal firms; confirms strong improvements in productivity even among small informal firms • Amiti and Konings (2007) find strong TFP improvements after trade liberalization in Indonesia • They find a stronger role for input tariff reductions; we (and Nataraj) find stronger role for output tariff reductions • De Loecker (2009) finds increases in productivity for Belgian textile firms following lifting of quotas (trade liberalization) • Ruiz and Utar (2009) find Mexican firms that compete closely with Chinese firms improved productivity following China’s entry into WTO • A recent literature review is in Holmes and Schmitz (2010, FRB-Minneapolis)

  18. Role of reallocation • Foster, Haltiwanger and Krizan (2001) for US (and studies for other developed countries) show reallocation of resources to productive firms/industries play an important role in aggregate productivity growth • Hseih and Klenow (2009) (consistent with earlier work by Duflo and Banerjee (2005)) find that reallocating to US efficiency levels could increase India’ manufacturing productivity by 40-60% (30-50% for China) • policies “constrain the most efficient producers and coddle the least efficient” • the most productive companies much larger in US • need to be cautious about studies of GDP share of “SMEs”; does a larger share suggest “good SME development” or “misallocation”? • E.g. Retail sector in India productivity was just 6% of US (McKinsey report, 1997). Among other important factors, two key policy factors : • restrictions on FDI (still not fully opened delaying Walmart retail entry) • restrictions on big stores due to tax and labor laws (smaller stores avoid both) • Caselli (2005) – holding productivity fixed, redistributing from agriculture to other sectors would reduce income inequality by 2/3

  19. Other drivers of productivity • Syverson (2010) surveys literature on productivity determinants • In addition to competition (induced by industrial policy/trade reforms) and access to inputs (trade reforms), other key sources include • Worker human capital -- but maybe small role per Fox and Smeets (2009) • Incentive pay for workers and human resource practices • Managerial talent and practices

  20. Human Resource Practices • Piece rates or output linked incentives could lead to large productivity improvements (and increased firm profits) (Lazear 2000) • Linking managerial pay to productivity of workers improves overall productivity (Bandiera et al 2007) • Where production happens in teams, • Group incentives and problem solving teams help increase productivity (Hamilton et al 2003, Boning et al 2007) • relative ability of peers and also social connections with peers affect productivity (Mas and Moretti, 2010, Bandiera et al 2010)

  21. Managerial practices and productivity • Economists have considered managerial talent/practices as a potential driver of productivity for long (Walker 1887) • Bloom and Van Reenen (2007) • Surveyed 734 US and European firms on about 18 management practices in 4 areas (operations, monitoring, targets and incentives) • found measures of “good management practices” strongly correlated with high productivity • Again more competition associated with better management • Family firms with CEO chosen as eldest son very badly managed • Bloom and Van Reenen (2010) and Bloom at al (2010) extended study to 17 countries • Key finding is that for less developed countries, low scores are because a large number of smaller firms are poorly managed (whereas for US relatively few are badly managed)

  22. Managerial practices and productivity • Bloom, EifertMahajan, McKenzie and Roberts (2010) conducted a randomized experiment • Random subset of textile firms provide management consulting advice • Find productivity gains for firms that received advice • Management practices encouraged were: • Factory operations: Tracking machines, breakdowns and keeping factory floor tidy • Quality control: Recording and formalizing ways to address quality defects • Inventory: Monitoring and tracking inventory • Human resources management: Performance driven incentives/defined job descriptions • Sales/order management: Tracking production per order (to improve pricing) • Study suggests lack of knowledge about management practices – firms unaware of good practices and underestimate how impactful they can be

  23. Conclusions • Industrial and trade policy • A large number of studies suggest increased competition from industrial and trade liberalization spurs productivity growth • Aggregate growth gains from reallocation to more productive firms after liberalization • Business practices play an important part in productivity • academic work has tested and found strong positive effects for a number of incentive pay, human resources and management practices • while results are intuitive, surprisingly these practices are not widespread , particularly among smaller firms in developing countries! • Competition could play a role in promoting adoption of these practices

More Related