1 / 44

Post-Keynesian models of growth and distribution

Post-Keynesian models of growth and distribution. Marc Lavoie. Outline. Old post-Keynesian growth models 1956-1962 Kaldor Pasinetti Robinson’s banana diagram The inflation barrier New Kaleckian growth models 1981- now The neo or post Kaleckian model 1990 – now Other controversies

imani-patel
Télécharger la présentation

Post-Keynesian models of growth and distribution

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Post-Keynesian models of growth and distribution Marc Lavoie

  2. Outline • Old post-Keynesian growth models 1956-1962 • Kaldor • Pasinetti • Robinson’s banana diagram • The inflation barrier • New Kaleckian growth models 1981- now • The neo or post Kaleckian model 1990 – now • Other controversies • Overhead costs • The normal rate of utilization in the long run • Productivity changes Third International Summer School on Keynesian Macroeconomics and European Economic Policies, Berlin, 31 July - 7 August 2011

  3. The old post-Keynesian model • This model arises from Kalecki’s macroeconomic equation and from Keynes’s fundamental equations of the Treatise. • Kalecki: profits = investment + consumption out of profits – saving out of wages • P = I + (1 – sp)P – sw(Y – P) • P(sp – sw) = I – sw.Y • P = (I – sw.Y)/(sp – sw) • P/Y = (I/Y – sw)/(sp – sw) • If sw = 0, then: • P/Y = (I/Y)/spand • P/K = (I/K)/sp that is, r = g/sp • This is the Cambridge equation Third International Summer School on Keynesian Macroeconomics and European Economic Policies, Berlin, 31 July - 7 August 2011

  4. The Kaldor-Robinson growth model • The rate of profit is determined by the growth rate and the propensity to save out of profits (in the simplified case). • If the growth rate is higher, then for given propensities to save, the economy requires a higher profit rate (P/K) and a higher profit share (P/Y). • If this is the case, there is not a unique Harrodian warranted rate of growth (I/K = s.Y/K or gw = s.(u/v), with Y/K = (Y/Yfc)(Yfc/K) = u/v • In the neoclassical view, variations in technology (v) allows for a multiplicity of warranted rates. This line of thought, however, is questioned by the Cambridge capital controversies. • In the old post-Keynesian view, it is variations in income distribution (the profit rate) that permits a multiplicity of warranted rates (g = sp.r). • In the new post-Keynesian view (the Kaleckian view), it will be variations in the rate of utilization (u) that allows many warranted rates (g = sp.mu/v). Third International Summer School on Keynesian Macroeconomics and European Economic Policies, Berlin, 31 July - 7 August 2011

  5. The Pasinetti correction (1962) • Pasinetti (1962) claimed that Kaldor (1956) had made a mistake by omitting that workers also can save. Thus, the saving function: • S = Sp + Sw = sp.P + sw.W • had to be rewritten as: • S = Sc + Sw = sc.Pc + sw.(W + Pw) • Assuming that the profit rate is the same for both classes, • Pc/Kc = Pw/Kw = P/K • And that in the long run, the capital stocks grow at the same rates: • Sc/Kc = Sw/Kw = S/K = I/K = g • It follows that: Sw/Pw = Sc/Pcand hence: • sw.(W + Pw)/Pw = sc.Pc/Pc so that: • sw.(W + Pw) = sc.Pw and finally • S = Sc + Sw = sc.Pc + sc.Pw= sc.P Third International Summer School on Keynesian Macroeconomics and European Economic Policies, Berlin, 31 July - 7 August 2011

  6. The Pasinetti paradox • Thus, we have a revised Cambridge equation, valid however only in the very long run, where: • r = g/sc • The propensity to save of capitalists (who earn only profits, not wages) determines the profit rate, independently of the propensity to save of workers. • This result, along with Kaldor’s equation, has given rise to over 500 articles or book chapters by 200 different scholars, many of which tried to see what conditions could be changed while keeping the Pasinetti paradox! Third International Summer School on Keynesian Macroeconomics and European Economic Policies, Berlin, 31 July - 7 August 2011

  7. Joan Robinson’s banana diagram • In her 1962 book Robinson adds a behavioural equation to the Cambridge equation (which determines the profit rate, or which is seen as the saving function). • gs = spr • The investment function, in its linear form, would be • gi = γ + grre • With a non-linear investment function, we would have two possible equilibria, one of them being stable. Third International Summer School on Keynesian Macroeconomics and European Economic Policies, Berlin, 31 July - 7 August 2011

  8. Stability analysis: the saving function needs to be steeper than the investment function g gs H gi gh* g0 L gL* r0 rL* ra rh* r Third International Summer School on Keynesian Macroeconomics and European Economic Policies, Berlin, 31 July - 7 August 2011

  9. The paradox of thrift in PK growth models Impact of a lower propensity to save gs(sp2) g gs H’ g2 H gi g0 r r0 r2 Third International Summer School on Keynesian Macroeconomics and European Economic Policies, Berlin, 31 July - 7 August 2011

  10. The inflation barrier: a higher growth rate requires a higher profit rate and a lower real wage rate, which workers will fight through wage inflation gs(sp2) g gs H’ g2 H gi g0 r r0 r2 Third International Summer School on Keynesian Macroeconomics and European Economic Policies, Berlin, 31 July - 7 August 2011

  11. The inflation barrier: a higher saving rate would allow to evade the inflation barrier for entrepreneurs with more spirits. gs(sp2) gs g H’ g2 gi g0 H r r0 r2 Third International Summer School on Keynesian Macroeconomics and European Economic Policies, Berlin, 31 July - 7 August 2011

  12. First problem with the old PK growth model • 1. Sraffians have critized the Cambridge relation, claiming that there was a confusion between the actual profit rate and the normal profit rate. For Sraffians, the growth rate may determine the actual profit rate, but not the normal profit rate. The latter is strongly influenced by the long-term rate of interest, itself influenced by the monetary authorities. • 2. Sraffians reject the compulsory negative relationship between the growth rate and the real wage rate. They reject the idea that a higher growth rate needs to be associated with a lower real wage (even at constant productivity). • 3. Thus they reject the concept of the inflation barrier. Third International Summer School on Keynesian Macroeconomics and European Economic Policies, Berlin, 31 July - 7 August 2011

  13. Second problem with the old PK growth model • This is a problem underlined by Davidson (1972), Asimakopoulos (1984), and Marglin (1984). • Kaldor-Robinson-Pasinetti assume that prices, via markups, adjust the profit share to the higher growth rate. • There is very little discussion of quantities: the rate of utilization is assumed to remain or to return at its normal rate. • When there is a discussion, the discussion is very confused: • ‘Thus when we descend from the clean air of a golden age, where normal prices always rule, into the fogs of historical time, our analysis cannot but be blurred and imprecise’ (Robinson 1956: 190). Third International Summer School on Keynesian Macroeconomics and European Economic Policies, Berlin, 31 July - 7 August 2011

  14. Davidson’s critique • “The neo-Keynesian models of Robinson, Kaldor and Pasinetti, which are more directly derived from Kalecki's work and Keynes's Treatise on Money ... lay emphasis on changes in the distribution of income and prices as the primary adjustment mechanism to short-period disequilibrium, and adjustments via changes in employment and output are considered either to be of secondary importance or assumed away. In Joan Robinson's model, if realised aggregate demand is below expected demand, then it is assumed that competition brings down market prices (and profit margins) at the normal or standard value of output.” (Davidson 1972:124-5) Third International Summer School on Keynesian Macroeconomics and European Economic Policies, Berlin, 31 July - 7 August 2011

  15. Marglin’s critique • `In the short run, fluctuations in investment demand are reflected in fluctuations in output; the rate of capacity utilization changes in accordance with aggregate demand.... But in the long run, ... there is no excess capacity to accommodate investment demand. Distribution must bear the brunt of adjusting aggregate demand to supply” (Marglin 1984: 474-5) Third International Summer School on Keynesian Macroeconomics and European Economic Policies, Berlin, 31 July - 7 August 2011

  16. Robinson’s failed traverse with higher profit margins • “Now let us suppose that Alaph entrepreneurs begin to form themselves into rings and raise prices.... As prices rise, with constant money wages, the volume of sales of consumption goods gradually falls (or rather fails to rise at its former rate). Workers become unemployed, and the utilisation of capital equipment in the consumption sector falls below capacity.... Initially employment in the investment sector is unaffected.... But with redundant equipment in the consumption sector the demand for replacements falls off, there is unemployment in the investment sector and a fall in the rate of profit. We may suppose that after passing through a period of disinvestment, accumulation recovers to its former level (though there is no necessary reason why it should do so).” (Robinson 1956: 77-8). Third International Summer School on Keynesian Macroeconomics and European Economic Policies, Berlin, 31 July - 7 August 2011

  17. Robinson’s claim • “Firms may be working plant below designed capacity and still charging the "full cost" prices at which they were earlier able to sell their normal capacity output', while assuming however that `competition (in the short-period sense) is sufficiently keen to keep prices at the level at which normal capacity output can be sold” (Robinson, 1962: 46). • `Although variations in the degree of utilization of capacity are admitted for the short period, Robinson excludes them as far as the long period is concerned‘ (Ciccone 1986: 22) Third International Summer School on Keynesian Macroeconomics and European Economic Policies, Berlin, 31 July - 7 August 2011

  18. The new PK model: Kaleckian model • Del Monte (1975), Rowthorn (1981), Taylor (1983), Dutt (1984) • Changes in quantities are the main driver. • It is assumed that income distribution variables, such as the markup, or the target rate of return, are exogenous. The feedback effects of growth or employment on income distribution are omitted in the simple versions. • The model is made up of three equations: the saving function, the investment function, and the pricing function. Third International Summer School on Keynesian Macroeconomics and European Economic Policies, Berlin, 31 July - 7 August 2011

  19. A summary of growth rate implications Third International Summer School on Keynesian Macroeconomics and European Economic Policies, Berlin, 31 July - 7 August 2011

  20. Equations of a simple Kaleckian model • The saving equation: gs = spr • The investment function is assumed to be the canonical Kaleckian investment function: • gi = γ + guu + grr • The pricing function, which depends on the profit margin m: rPC= P/K = (P/Y)(Y/Yfc)(Yfc/K) = mu/v • The realization curve or effective demand function (ED), combines gs and gi: • rED = (guu + γ)/(sp − gr) Third International Summer School on Keynesian Macroeconomics and European Economic Policies, Berlin, 31 July - 7 August 2011

  21. A change in income distribution • What happens if there is a reduction in the markup (or in the profit share) and hence an increase in the real wage (or an increase in the wage share)? • Initially, in the short run, as explained by Robinson (1956), there will be an increase in consumption, and hence an increase in the rate of utilization. • Initially, also there will be no change in the rate of profit, as long as we assume that investment (and propensities to consume) is not modified. Recall Kalecki’s equation! • However, the increase in the rate of utilization will eventually lead to an increase in the rate of accumulation (the accelerator effect) and hence in the profit rate! This is the paradox of costs! • Real wages, profit rates and growth rates all rise together. Third International Summer School on Keynesian Macroeconomics and European Economic Policies, Berlin, 31 July - 7 August 2011

  22. gs g gi A decrease in the profit margin g1* g0* u r PC ED r1* r0* rmic u u0* u1 u1* Third International Summer School on Keynesian Macroeconomics and European Economic Policies, Berlin, 31 July - 7 August 2011

  23. An important variant of the Kaleckian model: the Bhaduri-Marglin model • Bhaduri and Marglin (1990) and Kurz (1990) have argued that the canonical Kaleckian investment function ought to be replaced by another investment function, that would take into account the normal profit rate instead of the actual profit rate. Instead of: • gi = γ + guu + grr • They propose something like: • gi = γ + guu + gmm • Where m is some proxy of the normal profit rate, that is, the profit rate that would be realized if the economy were at the normal rate of capacity utilization: rn= mun/v • Bhaduri and Marglin, and most empirical research, take the profit share in national income as this proxy. Third International Summer School on Keynesian Macroeconomics and European Economic Policies, Berlin, 31 July - 7 August 2011

  24. Effects of an increase in the wage share in the Bhaduri-Marglin model gS0 I, S gS1 gI1 g1 gI2 g0 gI0 u0 u1 u1* q Third International Summer School on Keynesian Macroeconomics and European Economic Policies, Berlin, 31 July - 7 August 2011

  25. Effects of an increase in the wage share on u and g Third International Summer School on Keynesian Macroeconomics and European Economic Policies, Berlin, 31 July - 7 August 2011

  26. Controversy #1: Overhead costs • There is some tradition in taking overhead costs into consideration: Kaldor 1964, Harris 1974, Asimakopulos 1975, Rowthorn 1981, Nichols and Norton 1991, Dutt 1992, Palley 2005 . • Things are not so simple if we take overhead labour costs into consideration (Lavoie 1992, 2009). Why? • Then the profit share is endogenous and does not necessarily move along with profitability (the normal profit rate or the target rate of return incorporated into the markup pricing formula). • The following two graphs show that things can be quite complicated! Third International Summer School on Keynesian Macroeconomics and European Economic Policies, Berlin, 31 July - 7 August 2011

  27. Impact of an increase in the profit margin (the target rate of return or the normal profit rate) on the net profit share when the investment constant is positive πS2 π πS1 B2 π2 B1 π1 πD u u2 u1 Third International Summer School on Keynesian Macroeconomics and European Economic Policies, Berlin, 31 July - 7 August 2011

  28. Impact of an increase in the profit margin (the normal profit rate) on the (net) profit share, when the investment constant is negative π πS2 πS1 π1 πD B1 B2 π2 u u2 u1 Third International Summer School on Keynesian Macroeconomics and European Economic Policies, Berlin, 31 July - 7 August 2011

  29. Overheads • Overhead costs are particularly important now since it has been shown that the top centiles in income distribution earn most of their money through salaries and wage bonuses. • The impact on the economy also depends on how overhead salaries are included into the pricing formula (here it has been assumed that firms follow a target-return pricing formula and hence add overhead costs under the assumption that the firm operates at its normal rate of capacity utilization). • Thus changes in the wage share may underestimate the changes in income distribution which are occurring. • Also an increase in the proportion of wages going to overhead labour (supervisory workers) does not always have the same effect! Third International Summer School on Keynesian Macroeconomics and European Economic Policies, Berlin, 31 July - 7 August 2011

  30. US top .01% earners Third International Summer School on Keynesian Macroeconomics and European Economic Policies, Berlin, 31 July - 7 August 2011

  31. Third International Summer School on Keynesian Macroeconomics and European Economic Policies, Berlin, 31 July - 7 August 2011

  32. Inequality within the salary structure Third International Summer School on Keynesian Macroeconomics and European Economic Policies, Berlin, 31 July - 7 August 2011

  33. Macroeconomic impact of an increase in managerial costs, with target return pricing (positive or negative on u) r PC2 PC1 EDB B2 B1 rn EDA A1 A2 u un Third International Summer School on Keynesian Macroeconomics and European Economic Policies, Berlin, 31 July - 7 August 2011

  34. Impact of an increase in managerial costs on the net profit share, with target return pricing, when the investment constant is positive πS2 π πS1 B2 B1 πn πDB A1 A2 πDA u un Third International Summer School on Keynesian Macroeconomics and European Economic Policies, Berlin, 31 July - 7 August 2011

  35. Impact of an increase in managerial costs on the net profit share, with target return pricing, when the investment constant is negative π πS2 πS1 B2 πDB B1 πn πDA A1 A2 u un Third International Summer School on Keynesian Macroeconomics and European Economic Policies, Berlin, 31 July - 7 August 2011

  36. Controversy #2: Should the rate of utilization be equal to its normal value in the long run? • Several authors, mainly Marxist ones (Shaikh, Duménil and Lévy), but also some post-Keynesians (Skott), argue that the Kaleckian model is under-determined because it does not assume a mechanism that will bring back the economy to its normal rate of capacity utilization in the long run. • This has been the subject of several articles, both in the mid-1980s and also more recently. • It has been argued in particular that economists ought to be Kaleckians (or Keynesians) in the short run, but that they should be classical (Marxist) in the long run. Third International Summer School on Keynesian Macroeconomics and European Economic Policies, Berlin, 31 July - 7 August 2011

  37. Mechanisms that bring the economy back to the normal rate of utilization • The Cambridge price mechanism (Robinson) • The central bank (fear of inflation) (Duménil and Lévy) • The business fear of full employment or full capacity (Skott) • Some form of rational expectations (Shaikh) • Changes in the retained earnings ratio of firms (Shaikh) • See Hein, Lavoie, van Treeck (CJE 2011) Third International Summer School on Keynesian Macroeconomics and European Economic Policies, Berlin, 31 July - 7 August 2011

  38. The Kaleckian response • Firms are content with a large range of rates of utilization (Dutt). • Firms would like to bring the rate of utilization back to its normal value, but they face other constraints that stop them from being able to do so (Dallery and can Treeck). • The normal rate of utilization will adjust itself to the actual rates of capacity utilization (path-dependence, Lavoie). • See Hein, Lavoie, van Treeck (Metroeconomica 2011) • A mechanism to explore: scrapping unused machines Third International Summer School on Keynesian Macroeconomics and European Economic Policies, Berlin, 31 July - 7 August 2011

  39. The Kaldorian influence • Kaldor can be said to have a multiple influence on models of growth: • In arguing that the natural rate of growth is influenced by growth in demand; • In arguing about productivity effects; • In arguing about cumulative causation; • In introducing open economy constraints on growth. Third International Summer School on Keynesian Macroeconomics and European Economic Policies, Berlin, 31 July - 7 August 2011

  40. Productivity growth • Kaldorians have for a long time argued that supply-side growth is endogenous, thus predating the mainstream theories of endogenous growth. • This is the so-called Kaldor-Verdoorn law, for which there is a substantial amount of empirical evidence (McCombie and Thirlwall 1994, McCombie 2002) and the formal origins of which can be traced back to Kaldor’s (1957) technical progress function. • The Kaldor-Verdoorn law claims that there is a positive causal relation going from the growth rates of GDP to the growth rate of labour productivity. Third International Summer School on Keynesian Macroeconomics and European Economic Policies, Berlin, 31 July - 7 August 2011

  41. The Kaldor-Verdoorn law • In other words, demand-led growth will have an impact on the supply components of growth (Léon-Ledesma and Thirwall 2002, Dray and Thirwall 2011). • More simply, it is claimed that there is a positive causal relationship going from the growth rate of the economy to the growth rate of labour productivity (and even the growth rate of the labour force). • McCombie (2002, p. 106) says that the Verdoorn coefficient is in the 0.3 to 0.6 range, meaning that a one percentage point addition to the growth rate will generate a 0.3 to 0.6 percentage point increase in the growth rate of labour productivity. • This number is also consistent with the one obtained recently by Storm and Naastepad (2008). Their average estimate is 0.5 Third International Summer School on Keynesian Macroeconomics and European Economic Policies, Berlin, 31 July - 7 August 2011

  42. Productivity regimes (revised Storm and Naastepad) • λ = β0 + β1.g + β2.w • g = ε0 + ε1(w – λ) + ε2. λ = ε0 + ε1.w + ε3. λ • Where ε3 = ε2 – ε1 • λ is the growth rate of labour productivity; • g is the growth rate of the economy; • w is the growth rate of real wages . • If ε1 > 0 then we have a wage-led demand regime (as before) • The question then is whether productivity growth λ is also wage-led. • There are two effects: a direct effect through parameter β2; and a multiple indirect effect, through the Kaldor-Verdoorn effect. • Also, do increases in real wages lead to employment growth or not? Third International Summer School on Keynesian Macroeconomics and European Economic Policies, Berlin, 31 July - 7 August 2011

  43. Total productivity effect of an increase in the wage share, when the partial productivity regime is wage led Third International Summer School on Keynesian Macroeconomics and European Economic Policies, Berlin, 31 July - 7 August 2011

  44. Conclusion • The Kaleckian growth model is very flexible. • It has been used by authors coming from several schools of thought • It has allowed discussions between different traditions. • It has an empirical content. • It can also handle monetary matters (Hein) • And open-economy matters (Blecker) Third International Summer School on Keynesian Macroeconomics and European Economic Policies, Berlin, 31 July - 7 August 2011

More Related