1 / 41

The Demand for Medical Insurance

The Demand for Medical Insurance. Professor Vivian Ho Health Economics Fall 2009. These slides draw from material in Santerre & Neun, Health Economics: Theories, Industries and Insights, Thomson, 2007. Topics to cover:. A theoretical model of health insurance

kasi
Télécharger la présentation

The Demand for Medical Insurance

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. The Demand for Medical Insurance Professor Vivian Ho Health Economics Fall 2009 These slides draw from material in Santerre & Neun, Health Economics: Theories, Industries and Insights, Thomson, 2007

  2. Topics to cover: • A theoretical model of health insurance • When theory meets the real world...

  3. Logic • The consumer pays insurer a premium to cover medical expenses in coming year • For any one consumer, the premium will be higher or lower than medical expenses • But the insurer can pool or spread risk among many insurees • The sum of premiums will exceed the sum of medical expenses

  4. Characterizing Risk Aversion • Recall the consumer maximizes utility, with prices and income given • Utility = U (health, other goods) • health = h (medical care) • Insurance doesn’t guarantee health, but provides $ to purchase health care • We assumed diminishing marginal utility of “health” and “other goods”

  5. In addition, let’s assume diminishing marginal utility of income Utility Income

  6. Assume that we can assign a numerical “utility value” to each income level • Also, assume that a healthy individual earns $40,000 per year, but only $20,000 when ill Income Utility Sick $20,000 70 Healthy $40,000 90

  7. Utility when healthy Utility 90 A B 70 Utility when sick $20,000 $40,000 Income

  8. Individual doesn’t know whether she will be sick or healthy • But she has a subjective probability of each event • She has an expected value of her utility in the coming year • Define: P0 = prob. of being healthy P1 = prob. of being sick P0 + P1 = 1

  9. An individual’s subjective probability of illness (P1) will depend on her health stock, age, lifestyle, etc. • Then without insurance, the individual’s expected utility for next year is: • E(U) = P0U($40,000) + P1U($20,000) = P0•90 + P1•70

  10. For any given values of P0 and P1, E(U) will be a point on the chord between A and B Utility A 90 B 70 $20,000 $40,000 Income

  11. Assume the consumer sets P1=.20 • Then if she does not purchase insurance: E(U) = .80•90 + .20•70 = 86 E(Y) = .80•40,000 + .20•20,000 = $36,000 • Without insurance, the consumer has an expected loss of $4,000

  12. Utility 90 • A • 86 C B • 70 $20,000 $40,000 Income $36,000

  13. The consumer’s expected utility for next year without insurance = 86 “utils” • Suppose that 86 “utils” also represents utility from a certain income of $35,000 • Then the consumer could pay an insurer $5,000 to insure against the probability of getting sick next year • Paying $5,000 to insurer leaves consumer with 86 utils, which equals E(U) without insurance

  14. Utility 90 • A D 86 • • C B • 70 $20,000 $40,000 Income $35,000 $36,000

  15. At most, the consumer is willing to pay $5,000 in insurance premiums to cover $4,000 in expected medical benefits $1,000  loading fee  price of insurance • Covers • profits • administrative expenses • taxes

  16. Determinants of Health Insurance Demand • Price of insurance • In the previous example, the consumer will forego health insurance if the premium is greater than $5,000 • Degree of Risk Aversion • Greater risk aversion increases the demand for health insurance

  17. If there is no risk aversion, utility = expected utility, and there is no demand for insurance Utility A B $20,000 $40,000 Income

  18. Income • Larger income losses due to illness will increase the demand for health insurance • Probability of ILLNESS • Consumers demand less insurance for events most likely to occur (e.g. dental visits) • Consumers demand less insurance for events least likely to occur • Consumers more likely to insure against random events

  19. The horizontal distance between the utility function and the chord represents the loading fee that the consumer is willing to pay Utility Income

  20. Estimates of Price & Income Elasticities for Demand for Health Ins. • Price elasticities b/w -.03 and -.54 • At the individual level • Enrollment or premium expenditure • Elastic or Inelastic demand? • Income elasticities b/w 0.01 and 0.13 From S&N, Table 6-2

  21. Estimates of Price & Income Elasticities for Demand for Health Ins. • What about when employees are choosing between the menu of plans offered by their employer? • Range of choices is more limited • Price elasticites are found to range between -2 and -8.4, depending on age, job tenure, medical risk category • Dowd and Feldman 1994, Strombom et al. 2002

  22. Assumptions underlying the theoretical model of health insurance demand • Consumers bear the full cost of their own health insurance • Insurance companies can appropriately price policies • Individuals can afford health insurance/health care The above 3 assumptions do not always hold in the real world

  23. The majority of Americans have employer-provided health insurance • Employer-paid health insurance is exempt from federal, state, and Social Security taxes • Employee will prefer to purchase insurance through work, rather than on his own

  24. Employee Purchased $1,000 28% tax <280> after tax 720 insurance <50> net pay 670 Employer Purchased $1,000 insurance <50> subtotal 950 28% tax <266> net pay 684 Example: Insurance and take-home pay when income is $1,000 per week and income tax rate is 28%

  25. Employer Health Insurance Coverage of U.S. Population (percent)

  26. Consequences for costs • “Too many” services were covered by insurance • Coverage of more small claims increased administrative costs • Employers offering more than 1 plan often fully subsidized the more expensive plans

  27. Empirical Evidence • Long & Scott (1982) • Regression analysis of the determinants of % of compensation paid to employees as health insurance • Annual U.S. data 1947-1979 • N=32

  28. Empirical Evidence PCTHLINS = -8.64 + .0284 MTR + .0498 RFRAMINC (6.22) (3.98) (1.14) -.0094 UNION + .088 PCTFEM + .1283 PCTSERV (.57) (3.72) (5.52) R2 = .9968 PCTHLINS = % of compensation as health insurance MTR = average marginal tax rate RFAMINC = average real family income UNION = % of labor force unionized PCTFEM = % employees female PCTSERV = % employees in service industries

  29. Empirical Evidence • How does an increase in the marginal tax rate affect the worker’s compensation package? • The implied elasticity of PCTHLTINS with respect to MTR is 0.41. If a cut in the income tax rate is approved, will demand for health insurance rise or fall?

  30. Physicians & Managed Care • Traditional fee-for-service gives physicians incentive to “overutilize” medical services • Managed care: A broad set of policies designed by 3rd-party-payers to control utilization and cost of medical care: • utilization review • alternative compensation schemes • quality control

  31. Managed care and Physician Incentives • HMOs are a type of managed care organization, but there are a variety of HMOs • Staff model: Physicians employed by HMO on a salary basis • No incentive to over-provide care • Group model: HMO contracts w/ group practice, which is paid by capitation • Incentive to limit services

  32. Network model: HMO contracts w/ >1 group practice, all paid by capitation. • Incentive to limit services • IPA model: HMO contracts w/ multiple docs in various practices; paid by discounted fee-for-service • Some incentive to over-utilize

  33. Types of Managed Care Orgs

  34. Preferred Provider Organization • Insurer contracts w/ multiple physicians: but enrollees can pay higher deductible or copay to see physician outside network • Discounted fee-for-service • Some incentive to over-utilize

  35. Point-of-Service Plan (POS) • Insurer contracts w/ multiple physicians: but enrollees can pay higher deductible or copay to see physician outside network • Like a PPO • However, enrollees are also assigned a primary caregiver who acts as a gatekeeper to specialists and inpatient care

  36. Source: Kaiser Employer Health Benefits 2006 Annual Survey, Section 5

  37. Practice Question • If you had the choice between a traditional FFS plan with a 10% copay and a staff HMO with no copay, at what percentage difference in premiums (10%, 20%, 30%) would you be indifferent between the 2 plans? Do you think your choice is a function of your age/health status? • If you were elderly and/or sick, which plan would you prefer if they cost the same amount? Why?

  38. Provider Management Strategies • Selective contracting • MCOs will contract with an exclusive set of providers • Based on quality or cost-effective practice patterns • Physician profiling • MCOs monitor physicians’ track record regarding referrals, quality, patient satisfaction

  39. Provider Management Strategies • Utilization review • “determine whether specific services are medically necessary and whether they are delivered at an appropriate level of intensity and cost • Practice guidelines • Inform providers of the appropriate medical practice in certain situations • Formularies • restricted list of drugs physicians may prescribe

  40. Performance of MCO’s: Are they “good” or not?? • Ideally, MCOs should encourage preventive and coordinated primary care, which reduces the need for more expensive specialty/inpatient care • But most MCOs are concerned with short-term profitability • Why pay for cholesterol-lowering pills when the enrollee is likely to leave your HMO years before he has a heart attack?

  41. Performance of MCO’s: Are they “good” or not?? • In general, studies show that HMOs provide medical cost savings of 15-20%, mostly through reduced hospital care • The impact of HMOs on quality of care is less definite • Health care providers treat patients belonging to a variety of plans

More Related