1 / 60

Social Mobility Within and Across Generations in Britain Since 1851

Social Mobility Within and Across Generations in Britain Since 1851. Jason Long Department of Economics Colby College November 2008. Social Mobility in 19 th Century Britain Why Does Mobility Matter?. 1. Fundamental to our understanding of economic equality and “fairness” of society.

liam
Télécharger la présentation

Social Mobility Within and Across Generations in Britain Since 1851

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Social Mobility Within and Across Generations in Britain Since 1851 Jason Long Department of Economics Colby College November 2008

  2. Social Mobility in 19th Century BritainWhy Does Mobility Matter? • 1. Fundamental to our understanding of economic equality and “fairness” of society. • Importance of Distribution is obvious, and well-studied – income, earnings, wealth, etc. • But Mobility informs our understanding of a given distribution: two societies with identical earnings distributions but different mobility regimes are not equally equal (Stokey, 1996). Distribution → Equality of Outcome Mobility → Equality of Opportunity

  3. Why Does Mobility Matter? • Has implications for economic efficiency. • Social/Class rigidities can impeed efficient allocation of labor • If educational institutions and labor market fail to sort, select, and promote talent, allocation of human capital in economy is suboptimal • Landes (1969) very critical of late 19th century English economy in this regard, especially with respect to education • Can be crucially important for long-run path of public policy: Current perceptions of mobility and equality of opportunity → Preferences for taxation/redistribution → Continuting perceptions of mobility/equality • Piketty (QJE 1995) • Bénabou and Ok (QJE 2001) • Bénabou and Tirole (NBER 2005)

  4. Equality in 19th Century BritainWage and Wealth Distribution • Subject of economic inequality and “Kuznets hypothesis” has received much attention: • Williamson (1980, 1982, 1985): Pay ratios show Kuznets curve – stability from late 18thc until early 19th, rising inequality until mid-century, leveling up to WWI • Feinstein (1988): No trend during 19th century • Lindert (1986, 2000, 2002): Real inequality increased earlier than previously thought, from 1740 – 1810. Wealth inequality greater before 1914 than since 1950.

  5. Equality in 19th Century EnglandSocial Mobility: Empirical Evidence • Major work is Miles, Social Mobility in 19th and Early 20th Century England (1999). Also Mitch (1993) and Miles (1993). • 68% of sons in same occupational class as father from 1839-54, falling to 53% by 1899-1914. • “In terms of its inhabitants’ relative life chances, [Victorian and Edwardian England was] a profoundly unequal society.” • 20th Century Results: • Goldthorpe (1980): 51% in 1972 in same class as father 58% in same class as first full-time job Mobility trendless in 20th century: “Constant social fluidity” • Baines, Johnson (1999): Higher working class mobility (50%) in interwar London than in England from 1899-1914 (40%) • Dearden et al (1997): Father/Son earnings elasticity between 0.4 and 0.6

  6. Studying Mobility in 19th Century EnglandMarriage Registry Data • All previous national-level studies have relied on data from marriage registries. • 1836 Registration of Births, Deaths, and Marriages Act: church registers must record occupation of bride, groom, and parents • Advantages: (1) Unique in recording fathers’, sons’ occupations (2) Signitures provide proxy for literacy • Disadvantages • Excludes non-marrying population (10% of 45-year old males) • Includes only Anglican ceremonies (by 1914, over 40% of marriages were non-Anglican) • “Snapshot problem”: Father and son at point in time  Does not control for stage of life cycle • Cannot observe intra-generational mobility at all

  7. Research Questions • 1. What was the rate of intergenerational social mobility in nineteenth-century Britain? • How does controlling for life-cycle effects change what we know about mobility? • 2. How prevalent was intra-generational mobility? • How does it compare to mobility across generations? • 3. How does mobility in nineteenth-century Britain compare with Britain in the twentieth century? • What is the long-run trend in mobility? • 4. What were the determinants of mobility for the individual? • How important were human capital investments such as schooling and geographic mobility? • 5. How persistent was mobility across three generations?

  8. New Approach to Measuring Mobility: Linked Census Data • 2% Sample of 1851 Census 168,130 men in England and Wales • Match Criteria: • Name (phonetic) • Year of birth ( 5) • County of birth • Parish of birth + Complete-Count 1881 Census All 12,640,000 men in the census • 28,474 men in 1851 and 1881 • 16,829 sons in 1851 • 9,477 HH heads in 1851 20,269 sons in 1881 + Complete-Count 1901 Census 8,677 sons in 1901

  9. Example: William, William, and David Phillips

  10. Linked Data: Three Generations, 1851 – 1901 • End result: 54,218 males covering three generations from 1851 to 1901 • Inter-generational mobility, 1851–1881 • 12,647 father/son pairs where son < 20 years old in 1851 • Average age of father in 1851 = 41.5 years • Average age of son in 1881 = 38.0 years • Intra-generational mobility, 1851–1881 • 7,790 males aged 20-35 in 1851, 50-65 in 1881 • Inter-generational mobility, 1881–1901 • 4,071 father/son pairs where son between 10-19 years old in 1881 • Average age of father in 1881 = 46.7 years • Average age of son in 1901 = 33.9 years • Mobility over three generations, 1851–1881–1901 • 5,763 grandfather/father/son sets • Average age of grandfather in 1851 = 45.8 years • Average age of father in 1881 = 45.3 years • Average age of son in 1901 = 32.1 years

  11. Advantages of Linked Census Data for Studying Mobility • Controls for life cycle: “destination to destination” • Allows intra-generational mobility to be observed • Three generations • Nationally Representative • Large: High cell counts • Household background information: • Siblings, Birth order • Mother’s status • Servants • School attendance • Place of residence • Reveals geographic mobility along with occupational

  12. Measuring Mobility • Focus here is on occupational/class mobility, rather than on earnings mobility (more common in the economics literature), for three reasons: • It’s all there is. Census doesn’t include any information on wage, wealth, or consumption. • Subject to fewer transitory shocks than earnings, one of the principal empirical difficulties with modern earnings elasticity studies. • Captures more dimensions of an individual’s experience that may be related to views of mobility: • standing in the community (prestige) • control at work (supervisory v. non-supervisory) • ability to control hours, importance of risk (self-employed v. others) • manual v. non-manual • place of work (factory/office v. home/farm)

  13. Making Use of OccupationOption 1: Occupational Classification (Armstrong, 1972) • Class I. Professional etc., occupations • accountant, solicitor, surgeon, large employer • Class II. Intermediate occupations • bookkeeper, manager, farm foreman, • craftsman (employer) • Class III. Skilled occupations • blacksmith, nurseryman, weaver, craftsman (non-employer) • Class IV. Semiskilled occupations • agricultural labourer, flax dresser, • rat destroyer • Class V. Unskilled occupations • general labourer, rag & paper collector, • bone sorter 3.5% in 1881 15.5% 50.8% 17.8% 12.4%

  14. Making Use of OccupationOption 2: Imputed Earnings

  15. Intergenerational Social Mobility, 1851-1881Sons aged 0-19 in 1851, 30-49 in 1881

  16. Social Mobility 1851-1881Intra- and Inter-Generational Mobility

  17. Intergenerational Mobility: Controlling for Life Cycle EffectsLinked Census Data vs Marriage Registry Data

  18. Comparing Mobility Across Tables • Need a single metric that • summarizes difference in mobility across two tables • is not affected by differences in occupation structure across tables • can be tested for statistical significance • Use cross-product ratio(s). For matrix M, immobility mobility Invariant to different occupational distributions Multiplying rows, columns by constants does not change underlying row-column association Multiply row 1 by r1, row 2 by r2, column 1 by s1, column 2 by s2,

  19. Comparing Mobility Across Tables • Altham (1970): For two r s tables, measures how far the association between rows and columns in table P departs from the association between rows and columns in table Q. A simple likelihood-ratio 2 statistic G2 tests whether the matrix  with elements θij=log(pij /qij) is independent If d(P,Q) > 0 and d(P,1) > d(Q,1), greater mobility in Q (mobility is closer in Q than in P to what we would observe under independence of rows and columns.)

  20. Intergenerational Mobility: Controlling for Life Cycle EffectsLinked Census Data vs Marriage Registry Data

  21. Research Questions • 1. What was the rate of intergenerational social mobility in nineteenth-century Britain, controlling for life cycle? Higher than previously believed: Total mobility = 48% versus 35%, Upward mobility = 28% versus 18% • 2. How prevalent was intra-generational mobility? Mobility within work-life was common: 44% changed class from 20s to 50s, 25% of them moving up • 3. How does mobility in nineteenth-century Britain compare with Britain in the twentieth century? • What is the long-run trend in mobility?

  22. Comparing Mobility in Two Economies • Simple two-generation human capital model generates clear predictions. • Solon (1999, 2004), Becker and Tomes (1979, 1986):

  23. Comparing Mobility in Two Economies • Simple two-generation human capital model generates clear predictions. • Solon (1999, 2004), Becker and Tomes (1979, 1986):

  24. Comparing Mobility in Two Economies • Simple two-generation human capital model generates clear predictions. • Solon (1999, 2004), Becker and Tomes (1979, 1986):

  25. Comparing Mobility in Two Economies • Simple two-generation human capital model generates clear predictions. • Solon (1999, 2004), Becker and Tomes (1979, 1986):

  26. Comparing Mobility in Two Economies • Simple two-generation human capital model generates clear predictions. • Solon (1999, 2004), Becker and Tomes (1979, 1986):

  27. Comparing Mobility in Two Economies • Simple two-generation human capital model generates clear predictions. • Solon (1999, 2004), Becker and Tomes (1979, 1986):

  28. Comparing Mobility in Two Economies • Simple two-generation human capital model generates clear predictions. • Solon (1999, 2004), Becker and Tomes (1979, 1986):

  29. Comparing Mobility in Two Economies • Simple two-generation human capital model generates clear predictions. • Solon (1999, 2004), Becker and Tomes (1979, 1986): with the standard earnings elasticity regression function:

  30. Comparing Mobility in Two Economies • Simple two-generation human capital model generates clear predictions. • Solon (1999, 2004), Becker and Tomes (1979, 1986): with the standard earnings elasticity regression function: the model above implies

  31. Comparing Mobility in Two Economies • This implies that the intergenerational transmission of earnings will be greater (i.e. that mobility will be lower) when • Heritability of “intrinsic” human capital (λ) is greater • Human capital investment is more productive (θgreater) • Earnings return to human capital (p) is greater • Public investment in children’s human capital is less progressive (γ less positive) • Grawe & Mulligan (2002) and Han &Mulligan (2001) also show that • Mobility is lower where capital markets function poorly • Mobility is lower with more variance in ability

  32. Intergenerational Mobility from 1851 to the Present • 20th century data: Oxford Mobility Study (1972) • 10,309 males surveyed • Ages 20 – 64 (mean = 41.1 years) • Data on occupations: • Own occupation at time of survey • Father’s occupation when respondent aged 14 • Own first full-time occupation • Own occupation 10 years after first • Occupations coded into same five-tiered scheme (based on Registrar General’s 1951 occupational classification system)

  33. Intergenerational Mobility from 1851 to the PresentLinked Census Data vs Oxford Mobility Study (1972)

  34. Intergenerational Mobility from 1851 to the PresentLinked Census Data vs Oxford Mobility Study (1972)

  35. Mobility Trend, 1880-1970Degree of Association between Fathers’ and Sons’ Occupations

  36. Mobility Trends in Britain and the U.S., 1880-1970Degree of Association between Fathers’ and Sons’ Occupations Sources: Long, 2008; Long and Ferrie, 2008

  37. Research Questions • What was the rate of intergenerational social mobility in nineteenth-century Britain, controlling for life cycle? • How prevalent was intra-generational mobility? • How does mobility in nineteenth-century Britain compare with other countries then and with Britain in the twentieth century? • Britain became more mobile from 1880 to 1970 • Contrasts with Erickson and Goldthorpe’s finding of “constant flux” for many countries since WWII • Consistent with Miles finding of upward trend from 1839 to 1914 • Britain significantly less mobile in 19th century than U.S. • But, trends moving in opposite directions: mobility in the U.S. has declined dramatically since the 19th century.

  38. 19th Century British Mobility in Perspective • Social mobility was significantly greater than previously believed • Intragenerational mobility was substantial • Mobility in general, however, was lower than in 1970, and lower than in the 19th century U.S. • How do we explain the differences?

  39. Comparing Mobility in Two Economies • Intergenerational transmission of earnings will be greater (i.e. mobility will be lower) when • Heritability of “intrinsic” human capital (λ) is greater • Human capital investment is more productive (θgreater) • Earnings return to human capital (p) is greater • Public investment in children’s human capital is less progressive (γ less positive) • Capital markets function poorly • There is greater variance in ability

  40. The (Belated) Rise of Schooling in England • Education Act of 1870 establishes school boards; mandatory, government-funded primary education • Education Act of 1880: Set minimum leaving age to 10, heavily restricted to 13 • Leaving age periodically raised thereafter, to age 14 by 1900

  41. Research Questions • What was the rate of intergenerational social mobility in nineteenth-century Britain, controlling for life cycle? • How prevalent was intra-generational mobility? • How does mobility in nineteenth-century Britain compare with other countries then and with Britain in the twentieth century? • What were the determinants of mobility for the individual? • How important were childhood human capital investments and geographic mobility?

  42. Micro-Level AnalysisWhat were the empirically important determinants of mobility? • Simple reduced-form estimation of return to human capital and location characteristics: where h is a vector of human capital indicators p is earnings return to human capital l is a vector of location characteristics

  43. Micro-Level AnalysisWhat were the empirically important determinants of mobility? • For occupational mobility: where y* is true, unobserved job quality y is observed job class and p, pu > 0, pd < 0, u < 0, d > 0

  44. Accounting for Endogeneity • Structural mobility equations: where y is imputed wage h1 is an endogenous human capital indicator h2 is a vector of exogenous human capital indicators l is a vector of exogenous location characteristics z is a vector of variables that determine the choice of h1 Identification requires exclusion restriction(s): variable(s) in z not present in h2,l.

  45. Endogenous Migration Decision • (Internal) migration choice endogenous. • Expected wage/mobility gains influence location choice •  Potential selectivity bias • Structural Model of Endogenous Migration Choice: Move/stay choice and treatment effect of migration jointly estimated by maximum likelihood

  46. Identification • Identification comes from two sources: • Nonlinearity of model mi appears in wage equation, while mi* appears in migration decision equation • Variable included in z but excluded from x Not in town of birth in 1851 F = 371.51

More Related