200 likes | 425 Vues
1 3 . Altruism and sociality. Primitive animals are all the same. There is no individualistic behaviour. Higher animals evolved individualism. The highest birds and mammals evolved individualistic characters (moods), motions and fears.
E N D
13. Altruism and sociality Primitive animals are all the same. There is no individualistic behaviour. Higher animals evolved individualism. The highest birds and mammals evolved individualistic characters (moods), motions and fears. Classical population genetic does not predict individualism because it focuses on optimisation and equilibrium states that are the same for all members of a population. • Evolutionary theory has to explain: • Altruism (the help of others despite of own costs) • Cooperation of related and unrelated individuals • The evolution of cheating • Sexual selection (the existence of differentiated sexual behaviour and mating rituals) • Biased sex ratios (the prevalence of either males or females in a population) • The existence of highly altruistic insect societies (eusociality) • The existence of infanticide in many mammals and birds • The existence of homosexuality in many mammals and birds • The appearance of common beliefs and religion in man
The unit of selection and evolution Unicellular organisms Multicellular organisms Higher taxonomic level Classical population genetics (Fisher, Haldane, Sewall Wright) Species Population Wynne Edwards (1962)to explain cooperation Higher taxonomic level Group Species Family Population Individual A more liberal view sees any trait inducing carrier of information as a potential unit of evolution. These include genes, individuals, and even groups but not species. Cell Organelle Genome The basic unit is the gene as the smallest essential carrier of information Gene C. Richard Dawkins (1941- Nucleotid
The game theory approach The classical hawk and dove game • Assume two players: • a hawk that will always fight until injured or until the opponent retreats • a dove that will always retreat. • Contests are associated will potential benefits (B) and potential costs (C). John F. Nash (1928- John Maynard Smith (1920-2004) Hawk v. Hawk: Each contest has a 50% chance to win. The net gain is the difference between benefits and costs of the contest Hawk v. Dove: The hawk will always win The pay-off matrix Hawk Dove Hawk ½(B-C) B Dove 0 ½B Dove v. Dove: Each contest has a 50% chance to win. There are no costs Dove v. Hawk: The dove will always loose
The idea behind game theory is now to define equilibrium conditions that define which game (strategy = behavioural phenotype) will have the highest payoff in the long run. Maynard Smith defined such equilibria that cannot be beaten by other strategies as evolutionary stable strategies (ESS). Populations of individuals playing an ESS cannot be invaded by immigrating individuals or by mutants playing other strategies. The pay-off matrix Hawk Dove Hawk ½(B-C) B Dove 0 ½B The fitness Is H an ESS? If B > C, H is always an ESS because per definition 0 ≤ p ≤ 1. Is D an ESS? For H to be an ESS W(H) > W(D) For D to be an ESS W(D) > W(H) If B > C, D is never an ESS
The pay-off matrix What is if costs are higher than benefits C > B? Hawk Dove At equilibrium we have Hawk ½(B-C) B For C > B an ESS is to play hawk with probability p and dove with probability 1-p. Dove 0 ½B Even simple games favour mixed strategies. This is the start of individualistic behaviour. The Retaliator game(fight when meeting a hawk and retreat when meeting a dove) The Bourgeois game(fight when owner, retreat when intruder) Hawk Dove Retaliator Hawk Dove Bourgeois Hawk ½(B-C) B ½(B-C) Hawk ½(B-C) B ¾B-¼C Dove 0 ½B ½B-e Dove 0 ½B ¼B Retaliator ½(B-C) ½B+d ½B-¼C+g Bourgeois ¼(B-C) ¾B ½B Retaliator and a mixed strategy are the two ESS of this game. Realization depends on the initial frequencies of players. The Bourgeois is the only ESS of this game.
Local mate competition In 1967 W. D. Hamilton proposes that in the long run organisms should preferentially invested in the cheaper sex. The cheaper sex is the one that promises more offspring at equal costs. p: probability to produce a son; r: expected reproductive success, C: cost of reproduction Which sex to produce? The probability that a son reproduces is high The probability that a daughter reproduces is low • For a proper choice a female • needs knowledge about the actual sex ratio and • must have the ability to control which sex she produces Many Hymenoptera and some other insects have these abilities Mammals and birds perform selective infanticide
Two examples of sex ratio allocation Figs and fig wasps Parasitic wasps Agaonidae are closely connected to figs. Depositing eggs into the ovaries they pollinate figs. Males are wingless and mate only with the local clutch Secondary parasitism of the parasitoid wasp Nasonia vitripennis parasitoid of blow and fleshflies Sex ratio is defined as the proportion of males
Selective infanticide in man The sex ratio is the proportion of males: SR = males / (males + females) The normal cross cultural sex ratio at birth is 105 males to 100 females = 0.512 (range 101 to 107: 100) Some reported sex ratios in childhood of preindustrial societies: Inuit Eskimos: 0.67 Yanomamö Indians: 0.56 Cashinahua, Peru: 0.60 Rajput caste, India: > 0.9 Upper class medieval Florence: 0.57 • Selective infanticide in man is found in nearly all cultures. • Often it serves to • stabilize population size • to adjust sex ratios to marriage probabilities in cases of highly unequal reproductive success • to adjust to a culturally preferred gender (frequently the male gender)
Reciprocal altruism Reciprocal altruism beween non-related individuals needs: Blood sharing in the vampire bat • Long term association of group members. • Donorship can be predicted from past helping. • Roles of donors and recipients reverse. • Benefits of the recipients outweigh donor costs. • Donors can detect cheaters. Exponential vampire bat weight loss function due to starvation • Primary social groups contain 8 to 12 adults with depending young. • 30% of the blood sharing events involve adults feeding young other than their own. • Blood sharing intensity depends on the degree of relatedness. • Blood sharing is often reciprocal. • Cheaters have not been observed. Weight lost Donor Recipient Weight gained Time lost Time gained Benefits outweigh costs
Cooperative breeding and helpers at the nest In the pied kingfisher Ceryle rudis primary and secondaryhelpers at the nest occur. Helpers occur in many higher bird species and help adults to raise the offspring. Primary helpers are older sons that are yet unable to breed. They increase their fitness via their younger sisters and due to additional experience. Secondary helping males are unrelated to the pair they help. Secondary helpers increase their fitness due to the chance to become the widow’s mate if the breeding male dies.
The evolution of cheating or the Prisoner’s dilemma Assume two prisoners have the alternative either of defect the other or to cooperate. Defection means shorter imprisoning. B>C If both prisoners defect they do worse than if both cooperate. However cheating the other is superior irrespective of what the other makes. Hence pure cooperation can never evolve. The pay-off matrix Defect Cooperate Defect 0 0 0 B(A) Cooperate 0 B(B) C(B) C(A) Now assume an iterative game where the players play many times. What would be the best strategy? In the long run there are several possible strategies The prisoners dilemma cannot fully be resolved analytically. The first software solution was provided by Rapoport in 1980. One EES is Tit for Tat (defect if prior being defected and cooperate if the other prior also cooperated). Defect Cooperate Tit for Tat The program playedTit for Tat or reciprocal altruism. The other EES of this game is always defect. Defect 0 e 0 Cooperate -d g g Tit for Tat 0 g g
Inbreeding What is the probability for a children to get a certain allele from their grandparents? GM1 GF1 GF1 GM2 Grandparents GM1 GF1 GF2 GM2 A,B E,F C,D A,B C,D E,F G,H C,D Parents M F M F P(C)=0.25 P(C)=0 P(C)=0.25 P(C)=0.25 Ch Ch P(C)=0.125 P(C)=0.25 Childrens The probability that Ch gets allele C is 0.125. The probability that Ch gets allele C is 0.25. GF1 is already inbred The mean probability to get an allele X from one of the members of a lineage is called the coefficient of inbreeding. GM1 GF1 GF1 GM2 A,B E,F C,C C,C Sewall Wright defined this coefficient as M F P(C)=0.5 P(C)=0.5 Ch P(C)=0.5 The probability that Ch gets allele C is 0.5. rl→m is the path from l to descendent m and L the length of path i.
Inclusive fitness In the Hawk - Dove game the EES for C > B was B<pC → pB>C P was the probability of a trait to occur. This is formally identical with the probability of a gene to occur via descent, it is identical to the coefficient of inbreeding. William D. Hamilton (1936-2000) Hamilton’s rule of inclusive fitness A simple example Assume a new gene A that promotes parental care. The probability of transmitting A from mother to daughter is 0.5. Even if the mother would die due to parental care (cost = 1) two additional raised offspring (B = 2) satisfy Hamilton’s rule. 0.5 =1 / 2 Parental care should therefore be widespread in animals. In cockroaches (Phoraspis and Thorax) the young bite wholes in the mothers thorax to feed from their haemolymph.
Kin selection and the evolution of sociality Members cooperate but retain reproductive ability Part of the members loose own reproductivity in favour of other group members Individualistic life → Sociality → Eusociality (superorganisms) → Joined parental care and defence Cooperative breeding Most bacteria and single cell eucaryotes True multicellular organisms (Metazoa, Fungi, Plantae → → Colonies Isoptera (autapomorphy) Some Aphidae and Thripidae At least 14 independent lineages of Hymenoptera Eucalyptus ambrosia beetles (Australoplatypus incompertus) Sponge shrimp (Synalpheus regalis) Naked mole rats(Heterocephalus glaber and Cryptomys damarensis) Most ‘primitive’ animals and plants Social spiders, isopods, many insects,many fishes Higher birds and mammals → → Often intensive common parental care, aunt behaviour, playing groups, and group defence
All termites (Isoptera). They have male and female workers and different casts. All ants (Hymenoptera). They have female workers only and highly differentiated cast systems. Some eusocial Apidae and Vespidae (Hymenoptera). They have female workers only. Some Aphidae and Thripidae (Homoptera) have sterile soldiers. Sometimes rudimentary parental care. Two species of mole rats have non-reproducing workers and a queen. Colonies have up to 300 members. Some bumble bees and other Apidae species may be either solitary or eusocial depending on environmental conditions.
What favours Hymenoptera to become eusocial? Hymenoptera are haplo-diploid organisms Fertilized eggs become females Unfertilized eggs become males The haplo-diploid system Queen King Daughter Son Brother 0.5 0.5 0.75 0.25 0.25 0 1.0 1.0 0 0.5 1.0 0 0.5 0.5 0.25 Daughter King Queen Queen A,B King C The diploid-diploid system Queen King Daughter Son Brother 0.5 0.5 0.5 0. 5 0.5 01.0 0.5 0.5 0.5 1.0 0 0.5 0.5 0.5 Son A Daughter A,C Daughter King Queen Son B Daughter B,C Queen - daughter Queen - sister Hamilton’s rule of inclusive fitness Given that costs and benefits of reproducing are similar it pays for a hymenopteran female more to invest in her sisters than in her own brood. This explains why eusocial Hymenoptera all have sterile female workers and never sterile males.
For instance a hymenopteran female helps her sister at the cost of no reproduction. At equlilibrum the number of surviving offspring should be 2. Hence C = 2 The sister raises one additional offspring Even for one additional offspring of the sister it pays to resign of own offspring But be careful Most of the haplo-diploid Hymenoptera are solitary. The theory requires that queens a priori invest more in daughters than in sons. Interestingly, many Hymenoptera are able to decide whether to lay male or female eggs. They are able to controlsex ratios Termites are diplo-diploid
Eusociality and monogamy Phylogenetic analysis shows that all ancestral eusocial hymenopteran species were monogame. Polygamy has derived after the transition to eusociality. Polygamy never occurs in species with totipotent workers. From Hughes et al. 2008
Today’s reading The game theory site: http://www.holycross.edu/departments/biology/kprestwi/behavior/ESS/ESS_index_frmset.html Selfish gene theory: http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Gene-centered_view_of_evolution The evolution of eusociality: http://www.thornelab.umd.edu/Termite_PDFS/EvolutionEusocialityTermites.pdf Biology and sexual orientation: http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Biology_and_sexual_orientation http://www.newscientist.com/article/mg20427370.800-homosexual-selection-the-power-of-samesex-liaisons.html Biased sex ratios in man: http://huli.group.shef.ac.uk/lummaaproceedins1998.pdfand http://www.jstor.org/cgi-bin/jstor/printpage/00664162/di975349/97p0109i/0.pdf?backcontext=page&dowhat=Acrobat&config=jstor&userID=9e4b1f37@umk.pl/01cce4405a00501c7b1f1&0.pdfand http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Gender_imbalance Figs and fig wasps: http://www.figweb.org/Interaction/index.htm