1 / 22

Production of Physician Services

Production of Physician Services. Central actors on the S side of the medical market -Only 20% of health care expenditures are for physician services, but 70-80% are influenced by physicians' decisions Physicians’ roles in producing medical care:

Télécharger la présentation

Production of Physician Services

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Production of Physician Services Central actors on the S side of the medical market -Only 20% of health care expenditures are for physician services, but 70-80% are influenced by physicians' decisions Physicians’ roles in producing medical care: -Physician labor as an input in the production of physician services (one of the inputs in the production of health) -Physicians as entrepreneurs operating the "physician-firm", producing the final output of physician services

  2. The "Physician-Firm" How does theory of the firm apply to medical practice? • Firms hire and control the use of resources • Firms emerge when coordinating a production process is more efficient by "command and control" than by contractual relationships -Physicians could use contractual relationships for everything except the direct patient encounter (billing, scheduling, transcribing, lab tests, etc.) -Horizontal integration (group practice) and/or vertical integration (multispecialty group practice, physician-owned laboratories, and PHOs)

  3. Firms face 2 constraints: • Available production technology • D for their final product (Note: Do not confuse the aggregate D curve for physician services with the D curve faced by an individual physician-firm) -Physician-firm must pursue its objectives subject to these constraints

  4. What does the physician-firm attempt to maximize? • Standard theory of the firm  profits • Physician-firm’s objective function expanded to include leisure (physician's labor input determines leisure) and sometimes patients’ health ("altruistic" or "ethical" motivations) -Including health helps model trade-offs between conflicting objectives (e.g., profits vs. health under capitation; willingness to take advantage of superior information to increase profits) -Controversial: Why should health be in the physicians' objective function? How can we measure the extent to which physicians value health?

  5. Physician-firm’s final outputs are an array of diagnosis and treatment services • Physician-firm decides which inputs to use in conjunction with physician labor • Considerable latitude in substituting one input for another (isoquants are not L-shaped): -Less specialized inputs vs. more specialized inputs (e.g., NA vs. RN) -Sterilize and re-use supplies vs. disposables -Routine H & Ps or self-care counseling can be performed using lower-cost nurse labor rather than the physician's own time

  6. Some input substitutions are technically or legally constrained -Only physicians have certain skills -State practice acts forbid anyone other than a licensed physician to perform certain tasks even if the non-licensed individual has the necessary skills -Importance of legal restrictions demonstrated by the greater use of NPPs in the military health care system, which is not subject to state practice acts, and in states with less restrictive practice acts

  7. How much are physicians willing to substitute other inputs for their own time? Physicians don’t delegate enough tasks (use too much of their own high-cost labor in tasks that could be performed by lower cost workers) (Reinhardt, 1972; Brown, 1988). Why? 1) If physicians' derive utility from patients' well- being and believe their own time is more important than the time of less trained personnel, they might delegate fewer tasks than would appear optimal on purely economic grounds

  8. How much are physicians willing to substitute other inputs for their own time? (cont.) • Physicians have monopoly power, creating a "transfer pricing" problem (what implicit price should the physician-firm assign to physician labor?). The monopoly price at which it could sell physician labor to the outside world or the hypothetical competitive price? Optimal decision is choose the competitive price as the transfer price and build the monopoly power into the price charged for services. This results in choosing the resource cost-minimizing input mix (which will involve more physician labor than if the higher monopoly price were used) and the returns to owning a monopoly input can still be captured in the output price.

  9. Optimal practice size depends on scale and scope economies Sources of scale economies: -Sharing overhead -Ability to fully utilize specialized inputs -Cross-coverage Brown (1988) finds that group practices are 22% more productive than solo practices, primarily because of the ability to efficiently employ physician assistants

  10. Sources of scope economies -Ability to communicate with and obtain consultations from different specialties -Ability to share equipment or facilities common to different services/specialties -However, integration (w/other physicians and w/hospitals) may be motivated more by increased bargaining power than cost efficiencies

  11. How should performance be monitored and rewarded? • Issue faced by any organization • “Shirking" or excessive demands on shared resources (e.g., nursing, labs) are difficult to detect • Particularly important when physicians within a group receive a flat salary (regardless how their group is paid) -Salaried HMO physicians worked 93% of the hours of IPA physicians paid FFS, but only saw 80% of the patients -Tying compensation to group's profits provides incentive to be cost conscious, but incentive weakens with group size. Detecting shirking is more difficult in larger organizations, so MCOs and physician-run group practices use financial and non-financial techniques to monitor and influence physician behavior.

  12. Effect of financial incentives on resource use in HMOs Hillman et al. (NEJM, 1989): -HMOs w/salaried or capitated physicians achieved lower hospitalization rates than HMOs paying FFS -For-profit and group-model HMOs had lower hospitalization rates -Placing physician at financial risk (e.g., withholds) for “excess” utilization led to lower rates of OP visits and higher likelihood that the HMO broke even or earned a profit

  13. How do physicians control themselves? Kerr et al. (AIM, 1995) described management methods used by physician groups that contract with HMOs: -100% used gatekeeping and preauthorization for some services -Preauthorization more likely for more expensive procedures [9% for chest x-ray ($87) vs. 95% for MRI ($1241); 60% for IM subspecialty consults] -Profiling utilization patterns (79%; only half case-mix adjusted) -Clinical practice guidelines (70%) -Physician education (69%) -Denial rates for preauthorization requests <10%

  14. Fee-splitting and Self-referral Another manifestation of poor consumer information is inappropriate referrals or tests -PCP helps patient "shop" for a specialist, determining when referral is appropriate and to whom. If PCP receives a "kickback" from the specialist, referral decisions are distorted. This is not all bad: fee- splitting can discourage PCPs from performing procedures that would be better performed by a specialist. -Medical ethics has long opposed fee-splitting. Kickbacks are illegal in Medicare and Medicaid.

  15. Physician’s information advantage creates a conflict of interest in self-referral • Some physicians have a financial interest in lab, surgery or diagnostic facilities • Reports of shoddy lab work led to the Clinical Laboratory Improvement Act of 1988 (CLIA) • Compliance costs caused some physicians to close their labs, creating a trade-off between convenience and centralization in larger, better-regulated facilities

  16. Self-referral to physician-owned joint ventures • GAO (1989): physician lab owners ordered more and more costly tests; led to restrictions on referrals of Medicare patients to labs in which they have an interest • In 1992, AMA reaffirmed its stand against self-referral • GAO (1993): similar results for diagnostic imaging; 38 of 39 free-standing MRI centers in Florida were physician joint ventures; led some states to restrict self-referral - Scott and Mitchell (MC, 1994): labs owned by their referring physicians performed 50% more tests per patient and had higher markups and greater profitability

  17. Physician Labor in the Long Run: The Returns to Medical Education and Specialty Training Financial rewards are one important determinant of career choices: -Decision to enter medical school and subsequent decisions about specialty training can be analyzed as investments -In exchange for tuition, lost earnings, and long hours, physicians earn more than they would have had they gone straight to work after their bachelor’s degree -Time preferences: those with strong preferences for current consumption are unlikely to forego current income for extra years of training

  18. Financial analysis of “investment” in medical education using internal rate of return • Compared to not obtaining any professional degree (not obtaining any degree for the 1990 #s) • Except for 1955 & ’65, returns adjusted for hours worked • Real returns (inflation-adjusted) - Some assumptions varied across studies Rates of Return to Professional Training PhysiciansDentistsLawyersBusiness (MBA) 1990 19.4% 20.7% 25.4% 28.9% 1980 12.1 7.2 1975 11.6 12.3 7.1 1970 11.8 12.1 7.0 1965 24.1 1955 29.1 -Attractive real return (vs. 6-8% in stock market) -IRR does not reflect the absolute size of the return

  19. Specialty Choice IRR to specialty training vs. minimum residency training required for licensure Weeks et al. (1994): Overall return (college, med school and residency/fellowship) in procedure-based specialties 20.9% vs. 15.9% in PC; gap has narrowed slightly.

  20. Med students’ response to expected financial returns in different specialties

  21. Physician Labor: The Labor/Leisure Tradeoff • The “trick” economists use to derive the S of labor is to examine the D for leisure • Time not working in the labor market is defined as leisure • An hour or leisure is “purchased” by not working, forgoing the extra income that could have been generated - D for leisure can be converted into the S for labor because at any wage, the S of labor is 24 hours minus the D for leisure

  22. Hourly Wage Labor Supply Hours of Labor Physician Labor: The Labor/Leisure Tradeoff (cont.) • If leisure is normal, IE and SE work in opposite directions. At higher w, an hour of leisure “costs” more, causing substitution away from leisure. However, higher w increases income, increasing demand for leisure. If the IE is stronger at higher incomes, it eventually overwhelms the SE, leading to a backward bending S curve for labor. -Evidence from moonlighting by residents

More Related