1 / 33

Oligopoly

Oligopoly . An oligopoly is a market structure with a small number of firms together controlling the market. Oligopoly . There is no single model of oligopolistic behavior. In general there is a spectrum bounded by:. A Contestable Market Model . A Collusive Model .

duard
Télécharger la présentation

Oligopoly

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Oligopoly An oligopoly is a market structure with a small number of firms together controlling the market.

  2. Oligopoly There is no single model of oligopolistic behavior. In general there is a spectrum bounded by: A Contestable Market Model A Collusive Model We shall discuss these two general models and various forms within them

  3. Contestable Market Model In it’s extreme, this is a market structure where the firms in an oligopoly compete against one-another as if there was no oligopoly; that is they compete freely in the market. In general however there are degrees of this market structure. Oligopolies engaged in a contestable market model usually compete on the basis of price or market share but they use specific characteristics emerging from the fact that they are oligopolies to their benefit. We will examine some of these.

  4. Contesting the Market Based on Price This is the situation of price competition where firms in an oligopoly compete against one-another based on price. Consider the simple situation – without loss of generality – of a duopoly (a market with only two operators in it). Further assume that there is a simultaneous game established between them. That is, they make business decisions – set prices and quantities – independently of each other. (Remember this is a limiting case) Furthermore the two firms produce identical products and have identical cost functions

  5. Let us assume that the cost function for either firms is: The market demand seen by both firms: The marginal cost for a firm would be:

  6. In a pure competitive environment, both firms will be willing – would eventually have to – bring down their prices to the marginal cost (but not lower than it) For both firm A and B: Solving for one of the Q’s similarly And therefore

  7. Substituting in the demand equation: Total revenue: And a total cost of: Leaving a profit of: We will contrast this case with that of collusive behavior later in the lecture

  8. Price Leadership In some oligopolies, one firm sets the price and others follow. The firm that sets the price is called a: Price Leader How should the price leader set the price and output levels? Under this model, the price leader sets the price but allows all other smaller operators to sell at that price. Whatever amount the small firms DONOT supply at the price provided, will be picked up by the price leader.

  9. It is important to note: • The price leader controls the market. If a price follower tries to sell below the set price, the price leader will move in and take up that market share • The price follower cannot of course sell at a price higher than the one set by the market leader as there will be no incentive for the consumer to by at a higher price As such, prices stabilize at the price set by the price leader

  10. Setting a price – as a price leader: • As each small firm will take the price as given, they would produce output at the quantity such that their price equals their marginal cost. • As such a supply curve for each and therefore for all (as a horizontal sum of all their marginal costs) small suppliers may be obtained. • The demand curve of the dominant firm can be derived by subtracting the amount supplied by the small firms from the total amount demanded (note that demand varies with price. That is demand varies if different prices are set by the dominant firm and followed by the small firms).

  11. Thus the demand curve for the dominant firm D can be obtained as the horizontal difference at each price between the market demand curve and the supply curve of the dominated firms. • The dominant curve knows its marginal cost (MC). By determining the demand curve as above, it can set the price and quantity at a point where MC intersects its demand curve and as such maximize profits. • Of course, this would not necessarily be a point of maximum profit (usually it is not) for the smaller operators collectively or individually.

  12. Example: Home Depot A simplified demand curve for home improvement supplies in a given town is: The demand curve for the Mom and Pop home improvement store(s) in the same region is: Home depot’s marginal cost is:

  13. To derive the demand for Home Depot’s products: The price is therefore: Home Depot’s total revenue is of course:

  14. Marginal Revenue is: Setting this equal to marginal cost:

  15. Collusion and Cartels Conditions in oligopolistic industries often favor collusion amongst the organizations forming the oligopoly: Numbers are small, and Firms are aware of their interdependence Collusion has its advantages: Increased profit Decreased uncertainty Better opportunity to prevent entry of new players

  16. But collusion also brings forth some issues and problems: Unilateral breaking of collusion by one or a few firms may lead to substantial losses for those who have not broken collusion They are often forbidden by law or by cultural norms Even when no intent is there to break collusion, it is expensive to maintain a collusive agreement Products have to be homogeneous If collusion is in the open, it is often called a cartel and the action is called price or supply regulation Most national laws prohibit formation of cartels but they do exist as international entities. Examples include OPEC and IATA (International Air Transport Association)

  17. Breakdown of Collusion It is not surprising that collusive arrangements tend to break down. What happens however is that they usually break down, the market re-organizes, new collusions are formed only to break down again…… MC PC is price set by cartel PR is price set by rouge seller BC is the base cost @cartel BR is base cost rouge seller PC ATC PR BC Demand BR MR QR QC

  18. Given that demand in oligopolies is often extremely elastic with respect to price, it can be seen that if a seller cheats or even has a secret “side-arrangement” at a lower price, it can increase profits significantly. From game theory we know that if we engage in a one-shot or a limited horizon game, it pays to cheat if the consequences of cheating are bearable For a cartel participant, if the intent is to stay in the cartel, then cheating is not an option. However, the cartel participants know that the other participants are likely to break the cartel if opportunity arises and therefore the cartel will break anyway, so why not let it be them who breaks it and at least reaps the benefit?

  19. On the other hand, they know that the cartel’s survival is to their collective advantage and if there is no cheating, then it is best to stay in the cartel. They also know that if caught cheating, they may be punished. In final analysis, they would break cartel if they are confident that their cheating will not be discovered too early (see the mathematics of cheating in lecture 6) or that if discovered, the punishment will not be sufficiently harsh. The largest and most powerful players in the cartel would want the cartel to survive, why? They will do whatever it takes to keep it together…..

  20. They (and other cartel members) would expend effort to make it impossible to cheat. This is done two ways: • Regulation and watchdogs • Threat of severe punishment Regulation and use of watchdogs are instituted to make it systemically impossible to cheat Threat of punishment is there to make it psychologically and economically unprofitable to cheat

  21. When regulations and watchdogs are inadequate (often) or are corrupted, the first method fails Use of punishment is an interesting case: If punishment is harsh enough – it will work and will keep the cartel together (e.g. Colombian drug cartels) but only for a limited period. Often the “enforcer” becomes too powerful and triggers a rebellion that causes the cartel to collapse If they are not harsh enough– the cartel will fall apart Reality is though that as most “legal” cartels are international entities, punishment must be administered internationally and unless the commodity in question is of extraordinary value (e.g. oil) national governments will not unite to form an international “punishment” force. As such punishment often does not work over international cartels.

  22. Collusive Pricing Let us review the case of contesting the market based on price: We had: Total revenue: And a total cost of: Leaving a profit of:

  23. Now let us examine the case of a duopoly where there is collusion: The cartel’s marginal cost will be the horizontal sum of the two marginal cost curves, in our case: The cartel will set its marginal revenue equal to its marginal cost (as it will wish to act monopolistically)

  24. The marginal revenue will be: Setting marginal cost and marginal revenue equal: Substituting in the cartel demand curve, we get a price of $100-$38.4= $61.6 The cartel’s total revenue is $61.6 x 38.4 = $2,365.44 As each firm produces the same amount (38.4 / 2 = 19.2), they both have the same marginal cost (4+19.2 = $23.2)

  25. Also the firms likewise will split the total revenue: Each firm has a total cost of: Each firm therefore makes a profit of: This is more than 35 times the profit of $12 if they were to compete !!!

  26. Capacity (Quantity) Competition Given the difficulty of maintaining a collusive arrangement and the general social and legal undesirability of cartel arrangements, how can firms avoid the lose-lose situation of direct competition and approach the win-win of a cartel arrangement without collusion? The answer is to try to reach Nash Equilibrium. This can be done by competing on quantity (production capacity)

  27. Reaching a Nash Equilibrium – Cournot Solution Let us first make certain assumptions: • The firms move simultaneously • They have the same view of the market (e.g. they see the same demand curve) • Know each other’s cost functions • They optimize their quantity decision assuming the other firm’s quantity decision is given These are all reasonable assumptions.

  28. Using the details from the previous example, we now solve for maximizing profit when the competitor’s profit is maximized (Nash Equilibrium) Let us be firm A: We maximize profit when our total revenue PQA exceed our total cost maximally. Our marginal revenue is:

  29. To maximize profit, we set MC=MR This is called the reaction function of firm A (us). It tells us the profit maximizing amount to produce, given the output of our competitor. Because firm B has the same cost function, and both firms face the same market demand curve, firm B’s reaction function is similarly: Note that this does not need to necessarily be the case and reaction functions may differ. The analysis will however remain the same

  30. Solving the two equations for the two unknown quantities QA and QB will give the respective production quantities for each firm. It turns out that QA=QB=24 and as such Q=QA+QB=48 As P=100-Q, then price is P=100-48=$52 So each firm makes a total revenue of $1248 (52x24) and each firm’s total cost is $884 and each firm makes a profit of $364 Whilst this is not quite the profit that a collusive arrangement would yield, it is still over 30 times better than the pure competition price

  31. First Mover Advantage Does the early bird get the worm? Now, let us consider the situation where one firm gets to move (set quantity and price) before the other firm. This can be done right (when the price set is such that it maximizes the other party’s profit having now had to go second) or wrong (when the price set is not optimal for the adversary). If set right, our firm can rest assured that the adversary will not come into the market with a different price. Using the information from our running example: Let us say that we (firm A) move first.

  32. Our firm’s total revenue will be: Our marginal revenue is: So we will set our marginal revenue equal to our marginal cost:

  33. Substituting into firm B’s reaction function yields Therefore Q=22.86+27.43=50.29 Substituting into the demand curve function gives the price $49.71. Our revenue is $1,363.59 and firm B’s revenue is $1,136.33 Respective profits are (you calculate the costs): $377.71 and $283.67 It pays to be first – Early bird gets the worm

More Related