1 / 32

Chapter 3 Linear equations: further topics

Mathematics for Economics and Business By Taylor and Hawkins. Chapter 3 Linear equations: further topics. Chapter 3: Topics Covered. Solving linear equation with more than two unknowns Market Equilibrium: Changes in supply and demand Cost, volume and profit analysis Macroeconomic Models.

Télécharger la présentation

Chapter 3 Linear equations: further topics

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Mathematics for Economics and Business By Taylor and Hawkins Chapter 3Linear equations: further topics

  2. Chapter 3:Topics Covered • Solving linear equation with more than two unknowns • Market Equilibrium: Changes in supply and demand • Cost, volume and profit analysis • Macroeconomic Models

  3. Solving linear equation with more than two unknowns • A set of simultaneous equations may have: • a unique solution – this occurs when there is just one set of values that satisfies all given equations. • no solution - this occurs when the two (or three lines) are parallel and hence the lines never intersect. • an infinite number of solutions – this occurs when the two or three equations are actually equations of the same line. • Simultaneous equations with more than two unknowns can still be solved using the substitution method. • An example illustrates the techniques best.

  4. Solving linear equation with more than two unknowns • Example • x + 12y = 3z = 120 • 2x + y + 2x = 80 • 4x + 2y + 6z = 219 • Find the values of x, y and z that makes each of these equations true. • Step 1: Number each of the equations: • x + 12y + 3z = 120 (1) • 2x + y + 2z = 80 (2) • 4x + 2y + 6z = 219 (3)

  5. Solving linear equation with more than two unknowns • Step 2: Choose two of the three equations and multiply one or both of the equations through by a constant that will result in the coefficient if one of the unknowns being the same in both equations. • Equation (1) x 2: • 2x + 24y + 6z = 240 (4) • Step 3: Subtract one equation from another inorder to eliminate one unknown. • Equation (4) – Equation (2): • 2x + 24y + 6z – (2x + y + 2z) = 240 – 80 • 23y + 4z = 160 (5)

  6. Solving linear equation with more than two unknowns • Step 4: Using the same technique eliminate the same unknown from the third initial equation that you have not used yet. • Equation (2) x 2: • 4x + 2y + 4z = 160 (6) • Equation (3) – (6): • (4x + 2y + 6z) – (4x + 2y + 4z) = 219 – 160 • 2z = 59 → z = 59/2 • (note the intention here was to eliminate x so we could have combined the result with equation (5). However we have had the added bonus of eliminating y also and hence finding z).

  7. Solving linear equation with more than two unknowns • Step 5 would be to use the two new equations in two unknowns to solve for one of the unknowns using the row operation method. • But we can skip Step 5 and move onto Step 6 which is the substitute the value of the first unknown back into either of the equations with just two unknowns to solve for the second unknown. • Substitute z = 59/2 into (5): • 23y + 4(59/2) = 160 → 23y + 118 = 160 → y = 42/23

  8. Solving linear equation with more than two unknowns • Step 7: Substitute the values of the two unknowns into any of the initial equations to obtain the value of the third unknown. • Substitute in Equation (1): • x + 12(42/23) + 3(59/2) = 120 • x = 120 – 504/23 – 177/2 = 441/46 • Hence x = 441/46 (=9.59), y = 42/23 (=1.83) and z = 59/2 (=29.5). • You can check your results by using an online simultaneous equation solver such as the one at http://math.cowpi.com/systemsolver/3x3.html or use the techniques outlined in chapter 10.

  9. Market Equilibrium:Changes in supply and demand • The quantities of a good demanded or supplied are assumed to be dependent on a number of factors all of which (except price) are assumed to remain constant when we draw supply and demand curves. • Changes in any of the factors other than price (such as income, prices of an alternative good, tastes) will cause a shift or pivot in the demand or supply curve. • Consider the following demand curve: • Qd = 96 – 4P + 0.1M + 0.3Pa • where P represents price, M represents consumers income and Pa represents the price of some alternative good.

  10. Market Equilibrium:Changes in supply and demand • In order to find equilibrium we need to make some assumptions about the level of income and the price of the alternative good: • M = £2500 and Pa = £60 • We also need a supply curve: • QS = 6P • Equilibrium is where QD = QS. • 96 – 4P + 0.1(2500) + 0.3(60) = 6P • 96 + 250 + 18 = 10P • P = 364/10 = 36.4 and hence Q* = 6(36.4) = 218.4 • Consider this situation graphically.

  11. Market Equilibrium:Changes in supply and demand

  12. Market Equilibrium:Changes in supply and demand • Now consider a changes in tastes that increases demand for the good by 25%. The new demand curve is then: • 1.25 x Qd = 96 – 4P + 0.1M + 0.3Pa = 1.25 x (364 – 4P) • Qd’ = 455 – 5P • The new equilibrium would be: • 455 – 5P = 6P • 455 = 11P → P = 41.36 and so Q* = 6(41.36) = 248.16 • The chart shows the new equilibrium, note how the demand curve has pivoted outwards.

  13. Market Equilibrium:Changes in supply and demand

  14. Market Equilibrium:Changes in supply and demand • Now consider the situation in which instead of a percentage increase in demand, the consumers income is increased by 40%. • The new demand equation would be: • Qd’’ = 96 – 4P + 0.1M x 1.4 + 0.3Pa = 96 -4P + 0.1(2500)(1.4) + 0.3(60) • Qd’’ = 96 – 4P + 350 + 18 = 464 – 4P • The new equilibrium would be: • 464 – 4P = 6P • 464 = 10P → P = 46.4 and so Q* = 6(46.4) = 278.4 • The chart shows the new equilibrium, note how the demand curve has shifted outwards.

  15. Market Equilibrium:Changes in supply and demand

  16. Market Equilibrium:Changes in supply and demand • Information on quantity supplied is based on the prices that suppliers receive. • If a per unit tax is imposed, buyers will still pay a price of P per unit, but suppliers receive a price of only P-t. • Therefore a tax changes the supply equation and causes it to shift to the left. • Previously: • No tax: QS = 6P • With Tax: QS = 6(P – t) • If the tax is £2 then: • QS = 6(P – 2) = -12 + 6P

  17. Market Equilibrium:Changes in supply and demand • Consider the impact on the equilibrium following the imposition of a per unit tax of £4.50. • Previously: • Qd = 96 – 4P + 0.1M + 0.3Pa • where M = £2500 and Pa = £60. • Qs = 6P • and now Qs =6(P - t) = 6(P – 4.5) = 6P – 27 • Equilibrium is where QD = QS. • 96 – 4P + 0.1(2500) + 0.3(60) = 6P – 27 • 10P = 250 + 18 + 96 + 27 = 391 • P = 39.1 and hence Q = 6(39.1 – 4.5) = 207.6 • See diagram and note how supply curve shifts.

  18. Market Equilibrium:Changes in supply and demand

  19. Cost, volume and profit analysis • Consider the following definitions: • Profit (P) = Total Revenue (TR) – Total Cost (TC) • TR = Price (P) x Quantity (Q) • Total Cost (TC) = Fixed Cost (FC) + Variable Cost (VC) • Average Variable Cost (AVC) = Variable Cost (VC)/Quantity (Q) • Variable Cost (VC)= Average Variable Cost (AVC) x Quantity (Q)

  20. Cost, volume and profit analysis Example • A firm has FC= £555, AVC = £12 and is selling a good at a price of £17 per unit. • Find an expression for profit in terms of level of sales, Q. • What is the value of Q that will achieve a profit of £195? • At what sales level does the firm break even? • Plot the TR and TC functions to show the breakeven point.

  21. Cost, volume and profit analysis • (a) Find an expression for profit in terms of Q. • P = TR - TC = P.Q – (FC + VC) • P = P.Q – (FC + AVC x Q) • P = 17Q – (555 + 12xQ) • P = 5Q – 555 • (b) What is the value of Q that will achieve a profit of £195? • P = 5Q – 555 = 195 → Q = (195+555)/5 = 150 • (c) At what sales level does the firm break even? • P = 5Q – 555 = 0 → Q = (0+555)/5 = 111 • (d) Plot the TR and TC functions to show the breakeven point. • TR = PQ, TC = FC + VC = 555 + 12Q • See diagram.

  22. Cost, volume and profit analysis

  23. Macroeconomic Models • Consider the national income identity: • Y = C + I + G + (X – M) • where: • Y = National Income • C = Consumption • I = Investment • G = Government Expenditure • X = Exports • M = Imports • This identity is best illustrated with an example

  24. Macroeconomic Models • Example • C = 0.6Y + £120m • I = £45m • G = £634m • X = £160m • M = 0.45Y + £8m • Y = C + I + G + X – M • Y = 0.6Y + 120 + 45 + 634 + 160 – (0.45Y + 8) • Y = 0.15Y + 951 • Y(1-0.15Y) = 0.85Y = 951 → Y = £1118.82m. • This can also be illustrated graphically. • Note that the 45 degree lines shows all points were expenditure and income are equal.

  25. Macroeconomic Models

  26. Macroeconomic Models • Now let us consider some of the elements that male up this identity. • The consumption function was given as: • C = 0.6Y + £120m • This has two components: • £120 = autonomous consumption, that level of consumption that would occur even if income was zero. • 0.6Y = the part of consumption that is proportional to income. The 0.6 is referred to as the Marginal Propensity to Consume (MPC). • So if Income was £100 then £60 would be consumed and the remainder, £40, saved. Hence the Marginal Propensity to Save (MPS) is 0.4. • MPS + MPC = 1

  27. Macroeconomic Models Example • Consider what happens to the last example if the MPC increases to 0.7. • Y = C + I + G + (X – M) • Y = 0.7Y + 120 + 45 + 634 + 160 – (0.45Y + 8) • Y = 0.25Y + 951 • Y(1-0.25Y) = 0.75Y = 951 → Y = £1268m. • This can also be illustrated graphically. Note how the National Income Identity has pivoted upwards.

  28. Macroeconomic Models

  29. Macroeconomic Models • (X-M) represents the trade identity. If (X-M) > 0 then the value of exports is larger than the value of imports and the country is said to have a trade surplus. • If (X-M) < 0 then the value of exports is less than the value of imports and the country is said to have a trade deficits. • In our example the Import function was presented in two parts (M = 0.45Y + £8m). • This is similar to the consumption function where we have a autonomous imports (£8m) and a level of imports which is proportional to income. This is the Marginal Propensity to Import (MPM).

  30. Macroeconomic Models Example • Consider what happens to the last example if as a result of a Government “Buy British” campaign the MPM decreases to 0.35. • Y = C + I + G + (X – M) • Y = 0.6Y + 120 + 45 + 634 + 160 – (0.35Y + 8) • Y = 0.25Y + 951 • Y(1-0.25Y) = 0.75Y = 951 → Y = £1268m. • This is exactly the same outcome as the increase in the MPC.

  31. Macroeconomic Models Example • Consider what happens to the last example if as a result of an increase in world income exports double to £320m. • Y = C + I + G + (X – M) • Y = 0.6Y + 120 + 45 + 634 + 320 – (0.45Y + 8) • Y = 0.15Y + 1121 • Y(1-0.15Y) = 0.85Y = 1121 → Y = £1318.82m. • This can also be illustrated graphically. Note how the National Income Identity has shifted outwards upwards.

  32. Macroeconomic Models

More Related