1 / 29

A Parsimonious Model of Stock-keeping-Unit (SKU) Choice

A Parsimonious Model of Stock-keeping-Unit (SKU) Choice. Teck H. Ho Haas School of Business UC, Berkeley Joint work with Juin-Kuan Chong, NUS The Goal Search for best-fitting model in SKU choice. Purchase History of Panelist 14110874.

kioshi
Télécharger la présentation

A Parsimonious Model of Stock-keeping-Unit (SKU) Choice

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. A Parsimonious Model of Stock-keeping-Unit (SKU) Choice Teck H. Ho Haas School of Business UC, Berkeley Joint work with Juin-Kuan Chong, NUS The Goal Search for best-fitting model in SKU choice Teck H. Ho

  2. Purchase History of Panelist 14110874 Teck H. Ho

  3. Household i chooses a product (or stock-keeping-unit (SKU)) from a choice menu on a series of purchase incidences indexed by t Before each purchase incidence, each SKU j is characterized by a set of marketing-mix activities: price (P), display (D), and feature advertisement (AD) The modeler also observes: Household i’s SKU choices on purchase incidences 1, 2, …, t-1 The consumer choice setting Teck H. Ho

  4. To develop a good descriptive model of SKU choice to predict the probability of household i choosing SKU j on purchase incidence t Research question Teck H. Ho

  5. Criteria of a “good” model - Specification • Simple (i.e, small number of parameters) • Model complexity does not increase with number of items/feature levels in the choice menu • Increasing number of items • Satisfies plausible principles of human behavior • Incorporate psychological findings into model • Fits and predicts choice behaviors well (e.g., Guadagni and Little, 1983; Fader and Hardie, 1996) Teck H. Ho

  6. Complex menus & increasing number of items Teck H. Ho

  7. Criteria of a “good” model – Estimation • Does not aggregate choice (i.e., at the SKU level) • Heterogeneity across products (biased estimates); avoid “average” variables; inventory planning • Does not throw away observations • Choice-based sampling (biased estimates) (Ben-Akiva and Lerman, 1985) Teck H. Ho

  8. Criteria “violations” • Model specification • Model complexity • Many models have complexity increases with number of items • Plausible principles of behavior • Few attempts to incorporate findings from psychological research in consumer behavior • Model estimation • Aggregate choice • Violation examples: Brand-size combination; “other” product • Throwing away observations • Violation examples: Top n SKUs; ignore SKUs that have few purchases Teck H. Ho

  9. For estimation, every product category is assumed to have three attributes (Brand, Size, Flavor) Notations Examples • Household i Panelist 14110874 • SKU j UPC 11200000847 • Purchase Occasion t July 17, 97 • Attribute k Brand • Attribute level l COKE Teck H. Ho

  10. Utility specification • Utility = intrinsic value + value associated with marketing-mix activities • Error structure captures serial correlations in attribute-level and product-specific utilities • Uses latent class to capture heterogeneity • No product or attribute-level specific intercept terms! Teck H. Ho

  11. Intrinsic Value • Intrinsic value consists of both product-specific and attribute-level experiences • Example: SKU 14 = {PEPSI, 9.0, DIET}, Panelist = Grace Teck H. Ho

  12. Marketing-mix response • Control for price, display, and feature advertisement on local newspapers • Display and feature advertisement are dummy variables • Actual price paid (incorporating coupons and etc.) Teck H. Ho

  13. Previous Cumulative Reinforcement Product-specific Experience Consumption Incremental Reinforcement Shopping Previous Cumulative Reinforcement Size Attribute-level Experience Consumption Brand Incremental Reinforcement Flavor Shopping An overview of the model Intrinsic Value Utility Marketing-mix Response • Intrinsic value consists of both product-specific and attribute-level experiences • Consumption and shopping experiences depend on product and attribute-level familiarity Teck H. Ho

  14. Cumulative attribute-level reinforcement, Aikl(t) • Cumulative attribute-level reinforcement = Decayed previous reinforcement + immediate incremental reinforcement • Incremental reinforcement consists of consumption as well as “shopping” experience for chosen level and “shopping” experience only for unchosen levels Teck H. Ho

  15. Previous Cumulative Reinforcement Product-specific Experience Consumption Incremental Reinforcement Shopping Previous Cumulative Reinforcement Size Attribute-level Experience Consumption Brand Incremental Reinforcement Flavor Shopping An overview of the model Intrinsic Value Utility Marketing-mix Response Teck H. Ho

  16. Consumption (Cikl(t-1)) & shopping (Sikl(t)) experiences • Consumption & shopping experiences depend on consumer’s familiarity with the level • “Shopping” experience because people care about foregone utilities from actions/products that they could have chosen(Camerer and Ho, 1999) • Ck1 < 0 captures “law of diminishing marginal utility” • Sk1 > 0 captures “memory-based decision making”(Alba, Hucthinson, and Lynch, 1991) Teck H. Ho

  17. Variety-seeking behavior • Modeled as negative reinforcement (e.g., Lattin, 1987) • Under our model setup, it is driven by Ck1 < 0 (satiation) (Erdem, 1992; McAlister, 1982) or Sk1 > 0 (“grass is greener” effect) (Kahn, 1998) Teck H. Ho

  18. Product and attribute-level familiarities • Product and attribute-level familiarity is concave in number of times the product and attribute levels are consumed (Tikl(t) & Tij(t)) • Also tried linear and step functions • Log function fits best and is also the most appealing conceptually Teck H. Ho

  19. Main ideas • Utility consists of intrinsic value and value associated with marketing-mix response • Intrinsic value has two components: product-specific and attribute level experiences • Incremental reinforcement has both consumption and shopping experience, which depends on product and attribute-level familiarity • Each unchosen attribute level receives a different “shopping” reinforcement • The model has parameters for a K-attribute product category • Example: K=3 (brand, size, flavor), the model has 29 parameters Teck H. Ho

  20. Data Set • Panel-level market basket data set • 124,000 product purchases across 15 product categories (10 food + 5 non-food) • Purchases made by 513 households at 5 stores located within the same neighborhood over a 2-year period • + Data from Fader and Hardie (1996) Teck H. Ho

  21. Data Set Teck H. Ho

  22. Estimation • Maximize the likelihood of observing the data • The first 13 weeks of data for initialization; the next 65 weeks for calibration and the last 26 weeks for model validation • Benchmark against Fader and Hardie (1996)’s model Teck H. Ho

  23. FH Model • Has attribute-level specific terms • Does not capture familiarity-based consumption as well as shopping experience Teck H. Ho

  24. Key Results (Small Categories) • Number of parameters • Our model = 59 (two-segment models); FH model = 75-163 • Comparison was made on small product categories (less than 200 parameters) • Calibration • The hit probability is 7% better than F&H model • Better in every single product category • Validation • The hit probability is 8% better than F&H model • Better in every single product category Teck H. Ho

  25. Key Results (Small Categories) - Calibration Teck H. Ho

  26. Key Results (Small Categories) - Validation Teck H. Ho

  27. Key Results (Large Categories) Teck H. Ho

  28. Tests of Key Behavioral Premises Teck H. Ho

  29. Conclusion • Our model • Simple but fits and predicts better • Neither aggregates choice nor discards data • Shows both product and attribute-level experiences matter • Shows consumers accumulate both shopping and consumption experiences • IRI has implemented this model at a leading consumer packaged goods firm Teck H. Ho

More Related