1 / 53

The Physician Market, Part 1

The Physician Market, Part 1. Questions. Do physicians maximize profit? Are physicians constrained by market demand? Do physicians even set price and quantity? In what way do physician motives and power matter if insurance plans set price and quantity?

mevan
Télécharger la présentation

The Physician Market, Part 1

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. The Physician Market, Part 1

  2. Questions • Do physicians maximizeprofit? • Are physicians constrained bymarket demand? • Do physicians even set price and quantity? • In what way do physician motives and power matter if insurance plans set price and quantity? • This chapter will address motivation, market power, and price and quantity setting

  3. OUTLINE • Physician Market Structure • Conduct in the Physician Market • Physician Market Performance • Physician Practice Management Companies

  4. Physician Market Structure

  5. Physician Market Structure (cont.) *The AMA defines primary care as including family practice, general practice, internal medicine, obstetrics/gynecology, and pediatrics.

  6. Are there “too many” specialists and “too few” primary care docs? • Proportion of specialists in U.S. higher than in W. European countries and Canada (60% vs. 25-50%). • Specialists more prone to use new, high-tech medical procedues. • May explain why U.S. medical costs per capita are highest in the world.

  7. Matching Physician Supply & Requirements • “Future physician supply does not appear well-matched with requirements. (Politzer, 1996) • A shortage of 33,000 primary care physicians is predicted by 2020. • The same set of assumptions also generates a surplus of specialists.

  8. Distribution of Physicians by Mode of Practice • Most docs self-employed, but % is dropping. • Fall in solo practice docs, rise in salaried docs. • Reflects rise in ambulatory care by HMOs.

  9. Distribution of Physician Revenues by Source of Payer • % of revenues from Medicare/Medicaid high, but lower than for hospital sector. • % of revenues paid out-of-pocket also higher than for hospital sector.

  10. Managed Care Reimbursement of Physicians • MCOs hope to modify physician behavior in order to control costs. • 88% of all practicing docs in 2001 had at least one managed care contract. • In 2001, 49¢ of every $1 of physician revenue came from an MCO.

  11. Are there barriers to entry? • Requirements for licensure to practice • M.D. from accredited med school. • Internship or residency at recognized institution. • Pass a medical exam. • Advantage • Protects public from incompetent doctors. • Disadvantage • State licensure boards controlled by physicians who can restrict entry to keep salaries high.

  12. Is market reform better than government licensure? • Market reform may encourage physician monitoring better than government regulation. • More salaried docs are being monitored by HMOs. • Laws shifting medical malpractice liability towards hospitals and HMOs. • For-profit providers have direct financial stake in quality of their physicians.

  13. Production, Costs, and Economies of Scale • Do certain physician organizations have a production or cost advantage? • Group practice physicians are 22% more productive than those in solo practice. (Brown, 1988). • The lowest-cost practice size has been estimated at 5.2 physicians (Pope & Burge, 1996). • Economies of scale may exist for practices as large as 100 physicians (Marder & Zuckerman, 1985).

  14. Physician Market Structure Summary • Physicians have outpaced growth in the general population. • The U.S. may have too many specialists and too few generalists. • A move towards multi-physician practices. • Production & cost advantages. • Pressures of managed care. • Despite barriers to entry, competition is increasing.

  15. Physician Market Performance • Physician expenditures have slowed in the 1990s, more in line with the growth of the overall economy. But they may be on the rise again

  16. Physician Market Performance • Revenue per Self-Employed Physician, ($1,000s) • Increases in revenues are due to increases in expenses AND higher income for physicians

  17. Expectations (1999)

  18. Expectations (2011)

  19. Physician salaries remain high • When managed care grows, salary growth for specialists slows, while pay for primary care docs rises • Physician groups getting large enough to want their own specialists • Female docs’ salaries exceed males in a dozen or so specialties

  20. Average range of salaries for physicians 2010. Specialty Median salary (USD) • Anesthesiology 331,000 to $423,507 • Dermatology 313,100 to $480,088 • Emergency medicine 239,000 to $316,296 • Cardiac Surgery 218,684 to $500,000 • Family practice 175,000 to $220,196 • Internal medicine 184,200 to $231,691 • Neurology 213,000 to $301,327 • Obstetrics and Gynecology 251,500 to $326,924 • Ophthalmology 150,000 to $351,000 • Orthopedic surgery 397,879 to $600,000

  21. Average range of salaries for physicians 2010. • Specialty Median salary (USD) • Otolaryngology 191,000 to $393,000 • Pathology 239,000 to $331,842 • Pediatrics 160,111 to $228,750 • Psychiatry 173,800 to $248,198 • Radiology (diagnostic) 377,300 to $478,000 • Surgery (general) 284,642 to $383,333 • Urology 331,192 to $443,518 • Neurological surgery 350,000 to $705,000 • Plastic surgery 265,000 to $500,000 • Gastroenterology 251,026 to $396,450 • Pulmonology 165,000 to $365,875

  22. Employed vs. Independent Physicians • Employed physicians worked 5-7 fewer hours a week • Employed physicians’ median net income was $142,000 in 1996, vs. $198,000 for all private-practice physicians • Practice mgmt. Companies typically pay physicians $300,000-$400,000 per physician for practice assets (land, equipment) • Tradeoff:  20% of practice’s net revenues

  23. Physician Market Conduct • The legal environment and physician behavior. • The impact of managed care on physician conduct.

  24. Defensive Medicine & Malpractice Reform • Physician malpractice premiums account for 1% of US health care spending. • Physicians may over-provide care in order to avoid malpractice suits. • Defensive medicine may add another $4b to $25b to the nation’s health care bill.

  25. Defensive Medicine & Malpractice Reform • States which implemented direct reforms to their malpractice system (caps on damages, abolition of punitive damages) reduced hospital expenditures 5 to 9%. • Indirect reforms (caps on contingency fees, mandatory periodic payments) had no measurable impact on costs.

  26. Why do we have a malpractice system? • The malpractice system compensates victims for negligence and deters future negligence. • Tort Law: entitles an injured person to compensation as a result of someone’s negligence. • Damages include economic losses and “pain and suffering.”

  27. PROBLEMS WITH THE CURRENT SYSTEM • Physician Advocates • Too many of the claims filed are not due to negligence. • Juries award large sums unrelated to actual damages. • The threat of claims leads to “defensive” medicine, which adds billions to the nation’s health expenditures.

  28. PROBLEMS WITH THE CURRENT SYSTEM • Patient Advocates • The number of claims filed grossly underestimates the extent of physician negligence. • Large jury awards are infrequent. • Current quality control mechanisms are inadequate. • Defensive medicine is a byproduct of generous insurance coverage for patients, not malpractice insurance.

  29. Harvard Medical Practice Study (HMPS) • What is the incidence of “adverse events” and “negligent adverse events” in hospitals? • What are the total economic losses patients suffer from adverse events? • What fraction is covered by the tort system and other insurance? • What percentage of adverse events (negligent and non-negligent) lead to malpractice claims?

  30. SAMPLE • From 51 nonfederal, acute care hospitals in New York • 31,429 patients discharged in 1984 • Stratified sample based on hospital and patient characteristics • e.g. Geographic region, patients in high- risk specialties

  31. Criteria for an Adverse Event • A definable injury caused at least in part by medical management (negligent or not). • The injury must have produced measurable disability that prolonged the hospital stay or reduced function at time of discharge. • The injury must have been unintended.

  32. Which of the following is NOT an adverse event? • Intracerebral hemorrhage caused by anticoagulants • Incisional hernia • Amputation of a gangrenous leg • Fall from a hospital bed • Failure to diagnose an ectopic pregnancy

  33. Criterion for a “negligent adverse event” • An injury caused by the failure to meet standards reasonably expected of the average physician, other provider, or institution. • Rated on a 6-point scale. • Little or no evidence • Slight evidence • < 50:50 odds, but close call • > 50:50 odds, but close call • Strong evidence • Virtually certain evidence

  34. Was the following adverse event “negligible?” • During a therapeutic abortion after 13 weeks of pregnancy, the physicians unknowingly perforated the patient’s uterine wall with a suction device and lacerated the colon. The patient reported severe pain, but was discharged without evaluation. She returned one hour later to a hospital emergency room with even greater pain and evidence of internal bleeding. She required a two-stage surgical repair over the ensuing four months.

  35. Was the following adverse event “negligible?” • A patient with peripheral vascular disease required angiography. After the procedure, which was performed in standard fashion, the patient’s renal function deteriorated as a result of exposure to angiographic dye. The hospital course was stormy because of kidney failure, but the patient’s renal function slowly returned to normal. The adverse event caused a prolonged hospital stay.

  36. Determination of negligence is often difficult • Many medical procedures are inherently risky. There are uncertainties in diagnoses and treatments. • Physicians differ in the quality of care and success rates for reasons other than negligence. • Patients’ underlying health conditions differ.

  37. Determination of Adverse Events from Medical Records • Nurses and medical records administrators screened records for signals of adverse events. • Examples: Admission to any hospital after discharge, unfavorable drug reaction in hospital, neurologic defect at discharge. • Two board-certified internists of surgeons reviewed each screened record.

  38. RESULTS 31,429 in original sample 30,195 located on first review 22,378 negative for screening criteria 7817 positive for screening criteria Figure 1. The Record-Review Process. Numbers of medical records are shown. 7743 reviewed by physicians 6465 without adverse events 972 with no negligence 1278 with adverse events 306 with negligence

  39. Did the study cases sue for malpractice? • Further analysis was limited to 280 negligence cases which occurred or were discovered in the index hospitalization. • 98 / 31,429 patients filed claims against 151 health care providers. • Not all of these patients were victims of negligence, according to HMPS. • The sample estimates were re-weighted to represent the population of 2.7m discharges in 1984.

  40. STATEWIDE ESTIMATES 415 malpractice claims (2%) 27,197 adverse events due to negligence 26,764 with no malpractice claims (98%) 14,180 with strong evidence of negligence 12,858 with disability 7462 with disability <6mo (58%) 5396 with disability >6mo (42%) 2834 patients <70yo (53%) 2562 patients 70yo (47%)

  41. CONCLUSIONS • < 2% of patients identified as victims of negligence filed a malpractice claim. • Of the estimated 3570 statewide claims made in 1984, only 415 were defined by HMPS as negligent care. • Both patient and physician advocates have legitimate complaints. The current malpractice system does not do a good job compensating victims for negligence.

  42. FURTHER RESULTS • Only 50% of patient claims filed eventually receive some compensation. • About 1% of negligence victims receive some compensation. • The rate of adverse events differs by medical specialty, although the negligence rate is constant. • However, negligence rates vary across hospitals.

  43. Components of a Capitated Contract • Payment methods • Capitation rate/schedule - Managed care organizations employ actuaries who predict the cost of care as a function of population characteristics

  44. Physician induced demand • PID exists when the physician influences a patient’s demand to care against the physician interpretation of the best interest of the patient (Fuchs, 1978) • Influence v.s. Inducement • Undue influence • Utilization v.s. Demand • Changing utilization may not change demand • There are other ways to change demands (ration, efforts, etc)

  45. Physicians can alter the patient’s preferences • It has many direct policy implications • Training fewer surgeons will reduce the unnecessary surgery • To make physician fee policy within a budget constraint, it must be anticipated that fee reduction induces quantity increases

More Related