1 / 39

Bruno Contini with Matteo Morini University of Torino and LABORatorio R. Revelli,

Bruno Contini with Matteo Morini University of Torino and LABORatorio R. Revelli, Centre for Employment Studies JOB CHANGING BEHAVIOR: IS THERE A CASE FOR BOUNDED RATIONALITY ? September 2007 “fail often, fail better…” S. Beckett.

mick
Télécharger la présentation

Bruno Contini with Matteo Morini University of Torino and LABORatorio R. Revelli,

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Bruno Contini with Matteo Morini University of Torino and LABORatorio R. Revelli, Centre for Employment Studies JOB CHANGING BEHAVIOR: IS THERE A CASE FOR BOUNDED RATIONALITY ? September 2007 “fail often, fail better…” S. Beckett

  2. We observe the ex-post performance of job changers and establish the extent to which it suggests “fully rational” or “boundedly rational” behavior. Two contrasting hypotheses: Individuals choose to move or stay on the basis of subjectively perceived assessments of future (long run) wage growth risk of job loss arguments of a well defined utility function (known to the agents) OR boundedly rational decisions based on “satisficing” rules of thumb (or other “reasonable” criteria). In mainstream microeconometric explorations the hypothesis of full rationality is a given and never subject to test.

  3. real wage growth in a 3-year window after the job change Risk-on-the-job in a 3-year window after the job change This is what we might expect under full rationality…., and also under bounded rationality !

  4. DATA - Data from WHIP (Work Histories Italian Panel), employer-employee longitudinal panel random sample of all Italian employees of the private sector, observed at monthly frequency (at the time available from 1985 to 1998, now updated to 2003). The sample-population ratio is 1:90. Closed panel of male individuals working full-time in the private sector, age 30 -40 in 1986 (over 7000 individuals), observed from 1986 through 1996. Gender, age and working hours restrictions respond to the necessity to minimize heterogeneity of behaviour unrelated to job changing activities (maternity and child care, retirement choices, etc.).

  5. a pseudo-utility function as a plausible counterfactual As a plausible counterfactual (fully rational individuals) we assume a Cobb-Douglas utility function (U) in two arguments: the observed (ex-post) real wage growth over the future 3-year window (W), and a proxy of risk-on-the-job (ROJ) U = [(W)**n] / [ROJ**m] Workers accept job offers on the basis of two criteria: - if the wage offer is “sufficiently high” (i.e. higher than some unknown reservation wage); - if the offered position is subjectively perceived to be “sufficiently stable” (i.e. with a low probability of being dismissed or forced to leave). Both arguments imply a subjective judgement on the future evolution of earnings and on the quality of the job. Neither W, nor ROJ are known a priori. The robustness of the hypothesis of bounded rationality may be tested also by letting n and m take different values.

  6. BOUNDED RATIONALITY Agents set targets – aspiration levels – à la Simon, on the basis of “local knowledge”, and choose “satisficing” options with limited information / computational ability, The agents’ happiness depends on the difference between output y and aspiration level y* (alias reference point, alias norm in Akerlof’s terminology). Sophisticated versions of this model embody “loss aversion”: preferences are kinked at y*. The aspiration level is evolutionarily updated over time on the basis of performance and learning mechanisms. In our context, y* consists of a two-dimensional vector of long run wage growth and risk-on-the-job.

  7. BOUNDED RATIONALITY WHERE ? a lot of experimental and behavioral literature America’s mortgage business with subrprime borrowers (the most recent example) rational or behavioral investors ? (Guiso, Jappelli, Lusardi) consumer behavior in the credit card industry (H. Shui and L.M. Ausubel, 2004) purchase of large appliances (J. Hausman, 1979) purchase of flood and earthquake insurance (H. Kunreuther et al. 1978) reference based behavior of package deliverers (Fehr et al. 2007) = PROBABLY THE ONLY WELL-DESIGNED EXPERIMENT ON REAL ECONOMIC FACTS case-based decision theory (Gilboa – Schmeidler) = GAME THEORETIC APPROACH HOW ? WHY ? distaste for psychological transaction costs cognitive dissonance salience (the bias of attaching undue weight to recent events) social norms and gift advantages (Akerlof) slow learning and adaptation (in domains where the planning horizon is long and the stakes are high)

  8. MOVERS = individuals observed in different firms in 1986 and 1991. The three-year window is measured since the last relevant job switch. STAYERS = individuals observed in the same firm from 1986 to 1991 (careers possibly interrupted by short unemployment or temporary layoff spells in between). In testing modes of behavior, comparisons must involve individuals who have expressed a choice (voluntary movers and stayers). How to recognize Involuntary movers ? individuals found on a job in 1991, but have been – as it were -“forced” to leave a preceding position as a consequence of collective layoffs and/or incumbent industry or firm crises: at work in 1991 after having switched jobs in 1986-91; either (i) leaving firms that had closed and exited the market before 1991; or (ii) had undergone drastic workforce reductions before 1991 (> 40% of 1986 workforce). No way to single out voluntary vs. involuntary stayers. As will be seen, this makes our tests more robust !

  9. Dataset: stayers, movers 2723-1594 = 1129 Voluntary movers Stayers: 7.063 Movers: 2.723 205 1.594 Workers whose firm exits the market or exhibits a workforce decrease above 40% between 1986 and 1991 Involuntary movers

  10. Measuring real (long run) wage growth (W) STAYERS w3 = average yearly nominal wage earned during the 3-year spell started in 1990: w1 = average yearly nominal wage earned at the end of 1990. MOVERS w3 =average yearly wage earned during the 3-year spell after the job switch w1 = average yearly wage earned at the end of the period preceding the job switch. Nominal wages are deflated by CPI (p). W = real (long-run) wage growth W = w3/ p / w1/p The post change performance of movers and stayers is recorded through a sliding three-year window

  11. risk-on-the-job • ROJ = [predicted individual likelihood of dismissal 1986-91] / • [firm employment trend 1994 / 1991] • Suppose that Mr. X’s predicted likelihood of (past) dismissal is 0.30. If Mr. X stays at his firm of origin and such firm increases employment by 50% in the next 1991-94 period. Mr. X’s risk-on-the-job is reduced to 0.30/(1+ 0.5) = 0.20. If he moves to a different firm that cuts employment by 20%, his risk-on-the-job increases to 0.375 = 0.30/(1-0.2). • likelihood of dismissal prior to 1991 (NUMERATOR OF ROJ) • Likelihood of dismissal estimated on the open panel 1986-1991, including all full-time male workers aged 20-50. In 1986 the number of workers on payroll is 36,114; of these, only 15,394 are left by 1991. • Logit estimated separately for white and blue collars, against a set of covariates including age and age-square, wage, industry, location, firm size and firm employment trend, initial conditions and various interactions.

  12. (ii) projected employment trend (DENOMINATOR OF ROJ) Firm employment histories are observed through 1996. E(i, 1994) / E (i,1991) E(i) = total employment at i-th firm Is a simple indicator of firm-specific trend. The i-th movers’ ratio E(i,1994) / E(i,1991) is measured at the firm that made (i) a successful offer (around 1991). Nearly two thirds of the observable firms reduce their workforce in the 1991-94 period that falls around the 1993 recession: this is in line with well known trends of the Italian labor market.

  13. W = real wage growth Long run wage growth W: large variability among movers, smaller among stayers. Blue-collars = stayers do better in the low half of the distribution, movers in the upper half. White-collars = the movers’ performance dominates the stayers from P20 onwards.

  14. ROJ : movers are more exposed to the risk of job loss than the stayers (a result for which we find no precedents in the literature).  result somewhat blurred by composition effects….. 25% of the movers who switched jobs around 1991 end up in firms that exit the market before the end of 1994, while only 10 % of the stayers (who did not make the switch) are in the same position.

  15. U = W / ROJ BLUE COLLARS WHITE COLLARS

  16. U = W / ROJ**3 BLUE COLLARS WHITE COLLARS

  17. U = W**3 / ROJ BLUE COLLARS WHITE COLLARS

  18. <aspiration levels / reference targets> • strict “local knowledge” implies that search for better alternatives is often confined into: • same industry (11 manufacturing and service sectors) • same firm size (3 size classes: small (<20), medium (20-200), large (>200) • same skill level (blue and white-collars) • same location (3 geographical areas: North, Centre, South) • In principle 196 CELLS (reduced to 42 to preserve at least 10 individuals per cell). • Reference targets = percentiles of two distributions of theex-ante performance indicators (i.e. referring to the pre-job change window 1986-91), whose ex-post values measure performance • real wage growth W • likelihood of dismissal (ROJ) • We shall experiment with • Intermediate targets y*: [P 50 (W) & P50 (ROJ)] • High targets y** : [P66 (W) & P33 (ROJ)] • with no dynamic adjustment.

  19. Average euclidean distance D within cell around y*=(P50, P50) D(y*) = distances in the ordinate; U(y*) in the abscissa . Utility U is calculated at y* for each cell shows a large variability between cells. The (slight) negative inclination in the scatter suggests that cells closer to the unconditional efficiency frontier have less variability than the ones removed from the frontier.

  20. cells closer to the unconditional efficiency frontier in the <W-ROJ> space have less variability than those removed from the frontier Scatter of the reference points y*(k) in the space <W – ROJ> (cells k = 1,2, ,2,…..42) . Very similar to the unconditional scatter of all 7000 + observations The position of all cells is determined by industry differentials, skill differentials, firm size differentials.Cells in the N-W corner dominate those in the S-E corner.

  21. Same as before: in the <W – ROJ > space the circles, centered at y* - are proportional to (P90 – P10) of the U-function in each cell. The efficiency frontier – taken as P90 of the U-function for all the observations – lies to the left of the graph and cuts across only a few of the N-W cells • 1 most observations are very distant from efficiency frontier; • 2 movers’ search for new opportunities limited to own neighborhood…...

  22. % frequency of voluntary movers above efficiency frontier (p90 of different U definitions). Cells with < 10 observations removed

  23. INTER CELL MOBILITY • Mobility across cells is limited: • 40% of the movers do not change cell (specific human capital or limited search ? ) • 65% of the movers do not change industry (some moves take place across firms of different size) • EX-POST PERFORMANCE NOT DISTANT FROM REFERENCE POINTS • see slide no. 23 = 80% of individuals within circles centered at y* = p50, P50; • about 90% within circles centered at y* = P60, P40 (a more ambitious target); • very few above the overall efficiency frontier (9-th decile of U distribution).

  24. FREQUENCY ABOVE / BELOW REFERENCE POINTS If ex-post performance is symmetrically distributed around the median reference target (a modest achievement rate), we expect 25% of individuals to be found above BOTH targets simultaneously, and 75% below at least one. With more ambitious target [(y* = P66 (W); P33(ROJ)] the expected achievement rate will be 1/9 = 11%.

  25. Joint attainment (ABOVE) is larger than expected values under symmetry. Higher with respect to y* than y** (more ambitious target). In few cases (7 out of 42 ) the attainment of y* is less than 10%. Only in 3 cases do we find it above 50% with respect to y**. The relatively high frequencies of joint attainment are prerogatives of the white-collars (last cell digit is W)..

  26. In all cells, while the reference points y* are very different - some strongly dominate others - the % of individuals above / below y* is always quite constant. Suggestion: people are satisfied by relative positions that are roughly similar across cells, i.e. …..THE DEGREE OF INDIVIDUAL SATISFACTION IS A RELATIVE MATTER……..

  27. All the above results strongly suggest bounded rationality of the agents. • Under full rationality the following are to be expected: • - High(er) inter-cell mobility, reflecting substantial search activity across different industries and firm sizes; • Greater dispersion around reference points (reference points are irrelevant under full rationality); • More clustering in the vicinity of the efficiency frontier.

  28. Estimation of the wage / risk tradeoff • (i) OLS estimation • A trade-off between real wage growth and risk-on-the-job is reasonable among fully rational as well as boundedly rational agents. It is estimated – on (y – y*) differences - with the following linear model on all the (voluntary) movers: • [(W(i,k) - W*(k)] = a + b [ROJ(i,k) - ROJ*(k)] + c X(i,k) + d I(k) • + e INTER(i,k) + u(i) • X(i,k) numerical covariates; I(k) dummy of cell indicators: 2 skill groups, 9 industries, 4 geographical areas, 3 firm sizes; INTER(I,k): all relevant interactions. No endogeneity problems with ROJ as it is estimated from worker-specific covariates prior to 1991, and forward looking firm-specific elements. • Model (1) is similar – in deviations from w* - to the specification of <ln wage> • derived from theoretical equilibrium conditions of standard job search theory: • ln w (i) = f (B, theta, nu, r ) + g (X(i)-controls) + residuals (i) • B = unemployment benefits, a proxy of the reservation wage, theta = labor market thickness (or arrival rate of a job offer); nu = bargaining strength, a shift factor; r = a discounting factor incorporating all future dynamics. “Theta” and our “risk-on-the-job” convey similar (but opposite) concepts of job stability / instability

  29. Individual fixed effects removed • Individual fixed effects on wage growth are removed using the following strategy. • Let W(0,i) be the wage increase of the i-th individual in the time window 1986-81, and W(1,i) the same in the more recent !991-94 window. • We use the specification used in the OLS version, with X numerical covariates and I dummy-indicators, and take differences: • W (0,i) = alfa(i) + beta * X(0,i) + gamma * I(0,i) + res(0,i) • W (1,i) = alfa (i) + beta * X(1,i) + gamma * I(1,i) + res(1,i) •  delta W(i) = W(1,i) – W(0,i) = beta * [X(1,i) - X(0,i)] + gamma * [I(1,i) - I(0,i)] + [res(1,i) - res(0,i)] • which allows to retrieve "beta" and "gamma" coefficients non contaminated by individual effects. • beta^^ and gamma^^ are the non-contaminated estimates. We obtain non-contaminated predictors of W(1,i) as follows: W(1,i)^^ = beta^^ * X(1,i) + gamma^^ * I(1,i) + mean[W(0,i)] • and re-estimate (1) with W(1,i)^^ in place of W(i) • (2) [(W(i,k)^^- w*(k)] = a + b [ROJ(i,k)- ROJ*(k)] + c X(i,k) + d I(k) • + e INTER(i,k) + u(i,k) • .

  30. ESTIMATION OF TRADE-OFF EQUATIONS (1) and (2): DEPENDENT VARIABLE (W – W*), WITH W* = [P50(W), P50(ROJ)] (W - W*) and (ROJ – ROJ*) standardized before estimation OLS estimates after elimination of fixed individual effects in W White - 0.182 - 1.098 **** (ROJ - ROJ*) - 0.027 0.078 ** (ROJ - ROJ*) x white - 0.119 * 0.053 Small firm 1991 0.070 - 0.073 Large firm 1991 0.010 1.920 **** Moves 0.390 *** 0.094 * Ineq86 - 0.479 ** - 0.660 *** Ineq86 x white 0.400 ** 0.145 Industry dummies 1991 n.s. yes *** Age & age**2 n.s. n.s. ------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------ R**2 0.14 0.52

  31. OLS estimation  the trade-off between wage growth and risk-on-the-job is non- significant (and negatively sloped). • OLS with wage growth W replaced by predictor net of individual effects W* a significantly positive (and “rational”) tradeoff between wage growth (deviations from W*) and risk-on-the-job (deviations from ROJ*). • Additional indications: • white-collars severely penalized vis-à-vis manual workers • industry dummies very significant • large firm cells perform better than small & medium size • proxy of initial conditions (ineq86) highly significant: low starters do better than high starters • individuals who have switched jobs more than once (<moves>) are better off than the one-time movers (a “rational” choice if the first move was unsatisfactory) • High significance of cell indicators may be counter-intuitive, given that all observations, once expressed in deviations from relevant targets, are compressed towards the origin. But slide 20 - and XXX to be added - show that some cells strongly dominate others. White-collar cells are dominated; some industries and large firms outperform others.

  32. Slope negative and below significance Slope positive, well above significance. Two distinct clusters: big firms above; small firms below.

  33. [1] It could be argued that the result depends on our arbitrary parametrization of the utility function. If it were defined otherwise, say U = (G-w) n / ROJ m for other values of n and m, the conclusions may not hold. The following table displays values of P50/P90 for m=1 and different values of n. Changes are modest and confirm our intuition, including the one pointing at the higher variability of the movers’ performance vs. the stayers’. m = 1 n= 0.1n= 0.2n= 0.5n= 1n= 2n= 5Movers0.430.440.440.410.320.14Stayers0.610.600.600.580.540.40

  34. A quasi-counterfactual analysis: movers vs. matching stayers "how would the movers have performed had they decided not to move ?". each mover is linked to his observable co-workers (“matching stayers”). The stayer co-workers include voluntary as well as involuntary agents, and represent a quasi-counterfactual. The PREMIUM ratio, defined as PREMIUM= Performance (movers ) / Performance (median matching-stayers) indicates the relative performance of each mover vis-à-vis his matching stayers. Performance is W, ROJ and U. Among the white-workers, the median mover performs better than the median matching stayer: in about 60% of the cases we observe PREMIUM > 1. Among the blue- collars, instead, the comparative performance is split at the median (PREMIUM reaches 1 at P50).

  35. A quasi-counterfactual: PREMIUM = IND(movers) / IND(matching stayers) Wage growth (W) = 40% of matching stayers better off than movers (BLUE); 50% of matching stayers > movers (WHITE) Risk-on the-job (ROJ) = 60% of matching stayers better off than movers (BLUE and WHITE)

  36. PREMIUM UTILITY = W / ROJ 60 % matching stayers have higher utility than movers (BLUE) 50% matching stayers have higher utility than movers (WHITE) The answer to the question "how would the movers have performed had they decided not to move ? “ would be "the MEDIAN mover performs a little worse than his matching stayers". • (but conclusion strengthened by the fact that the comparison includes the involuntary stayers)

  37. PREMIUM (UTILITY) with varying parameters m and n MATCHING STAYERS VS. MOVERS UNDER ALTERNATIVE PARAMETRIZATION OF UTILITY only slight changes from previous slides

More Related