1 / 88

Multilingualism and Optimal Language Policy in the EU

Multilingualism and Optimal Language Policy in the EU. Jan Fidrmuc Brunel University. Stylized Facts. 6,912 living languages on Earth Most countries linguistically diverse.

ray-ball
Télécharger la présentation

Multilingualism and Optimal Language Policy in the EU

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Multilingualism and Optimal Language Policy in the EU Jan Fidrmuc Brunel University

  2. Stylized Facts • 6,912 living languages on Earth • Most countries linguistically diverse. • A few countries monolingual -- mostly small, remote and sparsely populated islands (e.g. Falkland islands, Saint Helena, Pitcairn), and. North Korea. • Most European countries linguistically diverse. • Most European countries: only a single official language.

  3. Stylized Facts • 2% EU citizens multilingual • 39% speak at least one foreign language • 14% speak two or more foreign languages • Source: Special Eurobarometer 243: Europeans and their Languages, November-December 2005. • Except English, French, German, Spanish and Russian, most languages only spoken in their own countries

  4. English

  5. French

  6. German

  7. Russian

  8. Stylized Facts • Large differences across age cohorts • Only English seems to improve its relative standing over time

  9. Stylized Facts: Attitudes • 67% Europeans think English is a useful language for one's personal development and career • 22-25% think so of German or French • 10% think no language is useful • The opinions on which languages children should learn are very similar • 2% think children should learn no foreign language

  10. EU Multilingualism and Optimal Language Policy • Outline • Multilingualism in the EU • Simple model of linguistic-policy choice • Cost per language per person: average cost vs cost per disenfranchised person • Optimal sequence of official languages • Political economy of a linguistic reform

  11. EU Multilingualism • EU in 1957: 6 members and 4 languages • EU in 2007: 27 members and 23 languages • Some official languages are spoken by many • German (85 mn), English (62 mn), French (61mn) • Some official languages are not • Maltese, Irish (0.4-0.6 mn) • Some non-official languages spoken by many • Catalan (4.1 mn), Russian (4.2), Turkish (2.2 mn), Arabic (1.6 mn)

  12. EU Multilingualism: Implications • EU treaties, regulations and decisions must be translated into all official languages • Most documents are prepared in English (62%), French (26%) or German (3%) • Translation: 1.3 million pages per year (2002) • 2710 translators and additional 1900 other staff • Interpretation: 50-60 meetings per day with 1-60 interpreters per meeting • 962 interpreters, plus 200 other staff

  13. EU Multilingualism: Implications • Long backlog of documents to be translated • Relay translations increasingly used • MEPs are asked to use simple sentences and to avoid making jokes

  14. EU Multilingualism: Future Prospects • Official status requested for Catalan, Valencian, Galician and Basque. • Future enlargements: Croatian and Turkish. • Alternatives: • English only; • English, French and German only; • Esperanto; • English (for everyone except English native speakers) and French (for English native speakers); • Those whose languages are used should compensate the others; • Self financing.

  15. EU Multilingualism • Language policy should facilitate communication effectivelyand efficiently • Most nation-states implement restrictive language policy: single language typical • EU: extensive multilingualism • This is effective but is it also efficient? • Costs and benefits need to be considered

  16. Costs • EU25 at ‘full speed’: € 1,045 million per year (17% of the administrative budget) • Erroneous and/or confusing translations • MEPs are asked to use simple sentences and to avoid making jokes • Potential for disagreements about interpretation of legal documents • Delays in implementation of legal/regulatory decisions

  17. Benefits: Preventing Linguistic Disenfranchisement • A person is linguistically disenfranchised (excluded) if the EU does not use a language that they understand • Not all languages are equal: some are more popular than others • Special Eurobaromenter 255: Europeans and their Languages, 2005 • Optimal language policy needs to reflect this

  18. Model of Language Policy Choice • Union with n linguistic groups • Population of group j is Nj • Population of the union is N= Nj. • Public good  • Language-dependent • Provided in a core language • Subsequently translated into other languages. • Translation can be full or partial • j ranges between 0 and 1 • Utility from receiving  in one’s own language: U(j), U’(j)>0 and U’’(j)<0 • Translation is costly: Cj=cj, c>0

  19. Model of Language Policy Choice • Individual utility from translation of  under self-financing • Optimal extent of translation, j, is chosen according to • Utility from translation of  under centralization • and optimal extent of translation, , is chosen according to

  20. 1. If all groups are equally sized, full sharing is preferred by all (except the core-language group): Model of Language Policy Choice 2. Optimal extent of translation regime depends on group size: full sharing results in over-provision of translation for small groups and under-provision for large groups. 3. Groups of below-average size prefer full-sharing while above-average ones prefer self-financing.

  21. Data on Language Proficiency • Eurobaromenter 54: Special survey on languages, 2000. • Candidate Countries Eurobarometer, 2001. • Special Eurobaromenter 255: Europeans and their Languages, 2005 • Respondents asked about mother’s tongue and other languages that they speak well • Nationally representative surveys • we can extrapolate to get the number of speakers of different languages in EU countries

  22. Not All Languages Equal

  23. Disenfranchisement • People are disenfranchised if the EU does not use a language that they understand. • Only preventing disenfranchisement considered • National pride, patriotism and international recognition are ignored.

  24. Disenfranchisement (EB 2000-01)

  25. Disenfranchisement corrected for proficiency (EB 2005)

  26. Cost per Language • Total cost: € 686 million in EU15, € 1,045 million in EU25. • Average cost per language per year: € 68.6 million in EU15 and € 55 million in EU25. • Average cost per person: € 1.8 in EU15 and € 2.30 in EU25. • There are important differences across languages.

  27. Average Cost per Person/Language

  28. Cost per Disenfranchised Person • Average cost misleading • Calculation assumes that all speakers of non-official languages are disenfranchised • Alternative: cost per language (€ 55 million) divided by the number of those who would be disenfranchised if their language was left out • Alternative scenarios: from English only to English-French-German • Static analysis, bargaining or sequencing not taken into account

  29. Cost per Disenfranchised Person

  30. Cost per Disenfranchised Person

  31. Optimal Sets of Official Languages • Selecting the optimal set of official languages • How many? • Which ones? • The optimal set of official languages should maximize welfare (facilitate communication) and minimize cost • For every m (1m23), we find the set of m languages that minimizes disenfranchisement ( minimizes welfare loss)

  32. Optimal Sets of Official Languages: All Respondents

  33. Optimal Sets of Official Languages: Respondents under 30

  34. Optimal Sets of Official Languages • Selecting the optimal m: • Marginal benefits  lowering disenfranchisement • Marginal costs  monetary and non-monetary • Costs and benefits not expressed in the same unit • 23 (or more) official languages inefficient • High costs and large negative externalities • 1-3 languages  excessive disenfranchisement • 63% with English only • 38% with English-French-German

  35. Optimal Sets of Official Languages

  36. Optimal Sets of Official Languages • 6 languages: good intermediate solution • Modest disenfranchisement: 16% • Adding further languages brings only limited gains • However, political constraints crucial

  37. Political Economy of Language-policy Reform • At present, linguistic policies decided by unanimity • Small countries benefit from cross-subsidization of translation costs by large countries • Two possible scenarios for reform: • Reform designed so as to compensate losers • Decision-making rule changes  qualified majority voting (QMV) instead of unanimity

  38. Political Economy of Language-policy Reform • Centralization: • Under-provision of translation for large countries • Over-provision for small countries • Majority of EU population would benefit from moving from centralization to self-financing • Majority of EU countries would oppose such reform • Reducing the number of official languages: similar case

  39. Political Economy of Language-policy Reform

  40. Language-policy Reform with Compensation of Losers • Decentralization: countries get control over funds earmarked for linguistic services • Giving countries discretion makes them internalize the costs of the linguistic regime • EU budget unchanged but funds spent in a way that maximizes aggregate welfare • Countries can keep the rents that they are currently enjoying  politically feasible

  41. Language-policy Reform under QMV • Alternative QMV scenarios: • Nice Treaty (min 14 states, 255/345 votes, 62% of EU population) • Lisbon Treaty (55% states, 65% pop)

More Related