1 / 36

Network Congestion Games

Network Congestion Games. Assistant Professor Texas A&M University College Station, TX. Evdokia Nikolova. TX. Dallas. College Station. Austin. Houston. Best route depends on others. Travel time increases with c ongestion. Highway congestion costs were $115 billion in 2009.

rona
Télécharger la présentation

Network Congestion Games

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Network Congestion Games Assistant Professor Texas A&M University College Station, TX EvdokiaNikolova TX Dallas College Station Austin Houston

  2. Best route depends on others Network Congestion Games

  3. Travel time increases with congestion • Highway congestion costs were$115 billion in 2009. • Avg. commuter travels 100 minutes a day. Network Congestion Games

  4. Example: Inefficiency of equilibria Delay is 1.5 hours for everybody at the unique Nash equilibrium 1/2 x hours 1 hour Town B Town A 1 hour x hours 1/2 Suppose drivers (total 1 unit of flow) leave from town A towards town B. Every driver wants to minimize her own travel time. What is the traffic on the network? In any unbalanced traffic pattern, all drivers on the most loaded path have incentive to switch their path. Network Congestion Games

  5. Example: Inefficiency of equilibria Delay is 2 hours for everybody at the unique Nash equilibrium 1 x hours 1 hour Town B Town A 0 hours 1 hour x hours A benevolent mayor builds a superhighway connecting the fast highways of the network. What is now the traffic on the network? No matter what the other drivers are doing it is always better for me to follow the zig-zag path. Network Congestion Games

  6. Example: Inefficiency of equilibria 1 1 hour 1 hour x hours x hours vs B A 1/2 1 hour 1 hour x hours x hours Adding a fast road on a road-network is not always a good idea! Braess’s paradox B A In the RHS network there exists a traffic pattern where all players have delay 1.5 hours. 1/2 Price of Anarchy: measures the loss in system performance due to free-will Network Congestion Games

  7. Game model • Directed graph G = (V,E) Multiple source-dest. pairs (sk,tk), demand dk • Players (users): nonatomic(infinitesimally small) • Strategy set: paths Pk between (sk,tk) for all k Players’ decisions: flow vector Sometimes will use for path flow. • Edge delay (latency) functions: typically assumed continuous and nondecreasing. Network Congestion Games

  8. Outline • Wardrop Equilibrium • Social Optimum • Price of Anarchy Network Congestion Games

  9. Outline • Wardrop Equilibrium • Social Optimum • Price of Anarchy Network Congestion Games

  10. Wardrop’s First Principle • “Travel times on used routes are equal and no greater than travel times on unused routes.” • Definition: A flow x is a Wardrop Equilibrium (WE) if for every source-dest. pair k and for every path with positive flow between this pair, where Also called User Equilibrium or Nash Equilibrium. • Equilibrium flow is called Nash flow. Network Congestion Games

  11. Outline • Wardrop Equilibrium • Social Optimum • Price of Anarchy Network Congestion Games

  12. Wardrop’s Second Principle • “The average [total] journey time is minimum.” • The cost of flow x is defined as the “total journey time”: • Denote , assumed convex. Network Congestion Games

  13. Wardrop’s Second Principle • “The average [total] journey time is minimum.” • Definition: A flow x is a Social Optimum if it minimizes total delay: flow constraints Network Congestion Games

  14. Social Optimum • “The average [total] journey time is minimum.” • Definition: A flow x is a Social Optimum if it minimizes total delay: Network Congestion Games

  15. Social Optimum • Definition: A flow x is a Social Optimum if it solves • Lemma: A flow vector x is locally optimal if for each path p with positive flow and each path p’, where Proof sketch: marginal benefit of marginal cost of reducing traffic on p increasing traffic on p’ Network Congestion Games

  16. Social Optimum (SO) • Definition: A flow x is a Social Optimum if it solves • Lemma: A flow vector x is locally optimal if for each path p with positive flow and each path p’, • Corollary 1: If costs are convex, local opt is a global opt, and lemma gives equivalent defn of Social Optimum. Network Congestion Games

  17. Social Optimum (SO) • Definition: A flow x is a Social Optimum if it solves • Lemma: A flow vector x is locally optimal if for each path p with positive flow and each path p’, • Corollary 2: If costs are convex, SO is an equilibrium with respect to modified latencies Network Congestion Games

  18. Social Optimum (SO) Mechanism Design Interpretation: If users value time and money equally, imposing tolls per unit flow on each edge will cause selfish players to reach the Social Optimum! • Definition: A flow x is a Social Optimum if it solves • Lemma: A flow vector x is locally optimal if for each path p with positive flow and each path p’, • Corollary 2: If costs are convex, SO is an equilibrium with respect to modified latencies Network Congestion Games

  19. Computing Social Optimum (SO) • Definition: A flow x is a Social Optimum if it solves • Corollary 3: If costs are convex, SO exists and can be found efficiently by solving convex program above. Network Congestion Games

  20. Outline • Revisit Wardrop Equilibrium • Social Optimum • Price of Anarchy Network Congestion Games

  21. Equilibrium existence • WE Definition: A flow x is a Wardrop Equilibrium if for every source-dest. pair k and for every path with positive flow between this pair, compare with: • SO Definition:A flow vector x is a Social Optimumfor every source-dest. pair k and for every path with positive flow between this pair, Network Congestion Games

  22. Equilibrium existence • WE Definition: A flow x is a Wardrop Equilibrium if for every source-dest. pair k and for every path with positive flow between this pair, where • SO Definition:A flow vector x is a Social Optimumfor every source-dest. pair k and for every path with positive flow between this pair, Network Congestion Games

  23. Equilibrium existence • WE Definition: A flow x is a Wardrop Equilibrium if for every source-dest. pair k and for every path with positive flow between this pair, where • Alternative SO Definition: A flow vector x is a Social Optimum if it solves: Network Congestion Games

  24. Equilibrium existence • Alternative WE Definition: A flow vector x is a Wardrop Equilibrium if it solves: where • Alternative SO Definition: A flow vector x is a Social Optimum if it solves: Network Congestion Games

  25. Equilibrium existence • Alternative WE Definition: A flow vector x is a Wardrop Equilibrium if it solves: where • Alternative SO Definition: A flow vector x is a Social Optimum if it solves: Network Congestion Games

  26. Equilibrium existence • Alternative WE Definition: A flow vector x is a Wardrop Equilibrium if it solves: • Theorem: A Wardrop Equilibrium exists and can be computed in polynomial time. Also, if program above is strictly convex, equilibrium is unique, up to same flow cost. Network Congestion Games

  27. Outline • Wardrop Equilibrium • Social Optimum • Price of Anarchy Network Congestion Games

  28. Example: Inefficiency of equilibria Delay is 1.5 hours for everybody at the unique Nash equilibrium 1/2 x hours 1 hour Town B Town A 1 hour x hours 1/2 Suppose drivers (total 1 unit of flow) leave from town A towards town B. Every driver wants to minimize her own travel time. What is the traffic on the network? In any unbalanced traffic pattern, all drivers on the most loaded path have incentive to switch their path. Network Congestion Games

  29. Example: Inefficiency of equilibria Delay is 2 hours for everybody at the unique Nash equilibrium 1 x hours 1 hour Town B Town A 0 hours 1 hour x hours A benevolent mayor builds a superhighway connecting the fast highways of the network. What is now the traffic on the network? No matter what the other drivers are doing it is always better for me to follow the zig-zag path. Network Congestion Games

  30. Example: Inefficiency of equilibria 1 1 hour 1 hour x hours x hours vs B A 1/2 1 hour 1 hour x hours x hours Adding a fast road on a road-network is not always a good idea! Braess’s paradox B A In the RHS network there exists a traffic pattern where all players have delay 1.5 hours. 1/2 Price of Anarchy: measures the loss in system performance due to free-will Network Congestion Games

  31. Price of Anarchy • Cost of Flow: total user cost • Social optimum: flow minimizing total user cost • Price of anarchy: (Koutsoupias, Papadimitriou ’99) Network Congestion Games

  32. Variational Inequality representation of equilibria Theorem: Equilibria in nonatomic games are solutions to the Variational Inequality (VI) where VI Solution exists over compact convex set with ℓ(x) continuous [Hartman, Stampacchia ‘66]. ∎ • VI Solution unique if ℓ(x) is monotone: (ℓ(x)-ℓ (x’))(x-x’) ≥ 0. [Exercise: verify] Proof: Flow x is an equilibrium if and only if ℓ(x).x <= ℓ(x).x’ . Proof: (=>) Equilibrium flow routes along minimum-cost paths ℓ(x). Fixing path costs at ℓ(x), any other flow x’ that assigns flow to higher-cost paths will result in higher overall cost ℓ(x).x’. (<=) Suppose x is not an eq. Then there is a flow-carrying path p with ℓp(x) > ℓp’(x). Shifting flow from p to p’ will obtain flow x’ with ℓ(x).x’ < ℓ(x).x, contradiction. Network Congestion Games

  33. Price of Anarchy with linear latencies Theorem**: The price of anarchy (PoA) is 4/3 in general graphs and latencies i.e. where x is WE and x* is SO flow. Pf: Network Congestion Games **References: Roughgarden, Tardos ’02; Correa, Schulz, Stier-Moses ‘04, ‘08

  34. Take-away points • Equilibrium and Social Optimum in nonatomic routing games exist and can be found efficiently via convex programs. • Social optimum is an equilibrium with respect to modified latencies = original latencies plus toll. • Price of anarchy: 4/3 for linear latencies, can be found similarly for more general classes of latency functions. Network Congestion Games

  35. References • Wardrop ‘52, Beckmann et al. ’56, … • A lot of work in AGT community and others. Surveys of recent work: • AGT Book Nisan et al. ‘07 • Correa, Stier-Moses ’11 Network Congestion Games

  36. Some open questions • What is the price of anarchy with respect to other Social Cost functions? • Dynamic (time-changing) latency functions? • Uncertain delays? Network Congestion Games

More Related