1 / 21

Autocorrelation II

Autocorrelation II. Lecture 21. Today’s plan. Durbin’s h-statistic Finite Distributed Lags Koyck Transformations and Adaptive Expectations Seasonality Testing in the presence of higher order serially correlated forms. 0. 2. 4. d = 0.331. 1.475. d L. 4-d U. 4-d L. d U. H 0 :  = 0.

tate
Télécharger la présentation

Autocorrelation II

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Autocorrelation II Lecture 21

  2. Today’s plan • Durbin’s h-statistic • Finite Distributed Lags • Koyck Transformations and Adaptive Expectations • Seasonality • Testing in the presence of higher order serially correlated forms.

  3. 0 2 4 d = 0.331 1.475 dL 4-dU 4-dL dU H0:  =0 H1 H1 Reject null Reject null Accept null Returning to the Durbin-Watson • Last time we talked about how to test for autocorrelation using the Durbin-Watson test • We found autocorrelation in the data in L_20.xls • We used this figure:

  4. Generalized least squares (3) • Need an estimate of  : we can transform the variables such that: where: • Known as Cochrane-Orcutt transformation. • Estimating equation (3) allows us to estimate in the presence of first-order autocorrelation

  5. Problems 1) The model presented by may still have some autocorrelation • the D-W test doesn’t tell us anything about this • we have to retest the model 2) We may lose information when we lag our variables • to get around this information loss, we can use the Prais-Winsten formula to transform the model:

  6. Problems (2) 3) We might want to include a lagged endogenous variable in the model • including the lagged endogenous variable Yt-1 biases the Durbin-Watson test towards 2 • this means it’s biased towards the null of no autocorrelation • in this instance, we’ll use Durbin’s h-statistic (1970): v = square of the standard error on the coefficient (g) of the lagged endogenous variable

  7. Durbin’s h-statistic • Durbin’s h-statistic is normally distributed and is approximated by the z-statistic (standard normal) • null hypothesis: H0:  = 0 • the null can be rejected at the 5% level of significance • L21.xls has example. • Problems with the h-statistic • the product nv must be less than one (where n = # of observations) • if nv  1, the h-statistic is undefined

  8. A note on consistency • Model with lagged endogenous variable and first-order serially correlated error may be mis-specified. Yt = b0 + b1Yt-1 + ut and ut = rut-1 + et • If so, presence of first-order serial correlation may induce omitted variable bias. • Need to include additional lagged endogenous variable term: Yt = a0 + a1Yt-1 + a2Yt-2 + et

  9. Why lags? • This mainly relates to macroeconomic models • economic events such as consumer expenditure, production, or investment • for instance: consumer expenditure this year may be related to consumer expenditure last year • In a general distributed lag model: Yt = a + b0Xt + b1Xt-1 +…+bkXt-k + et • where k = any large number less than t-2 • can eliminate coefficients b1 to bk by using a t-test • number of lags included is ad-hoc

  10. Problems for OLS • Lags lead to severe problems for ordinary least squares • loss of information (degrees of freedom) • independent variables (X) are highly correlated [multi-collinearity problem]

  11. Why lags are useful • Psychological reasons: behavior is habit-forming • so things like labor market behavior and patterns of money holding can be captured using lags • Technological reasons: a firm’s production pattern • Institutional: unions • Multipliers: short run and long run multipliers (how to read finite distributed lags in a model).

  12. Ad-hoc nature of lags • What can we do? • Two approaches • Koyck transformation • Adaptive expectations • Different implications on the assumptions about economic processes • will end up with the same estimating equation • looking only at the end product, we won’t be able to tell the Koyck transformation from adaptive expectations

  13. Koyck transformation • Model: Yt = a + b0Xt + b1Xt-1 +…+bkXt-k + et • The Koyck transformation suggests that the further back in time we go, the less important is that factor • for instance, information from 10 years ago vs. information from last year • The transformation suggests: Where 0 <  < 1 j = 1,…k

  14. Koyck transformation (2) • So, • Can use the expression for bj to rewrite the model Yt = a + b0 (Xt + Xt-1 + 2Xt-2 + ….+ kXt-k) + et(4) • this imposes the assumption that earlier information is relatively less important • Lagging the equation and multiplying it by , we get: Yt-1 = a + b0 (Xt-1 + 2Xt-2 + ….+ kXt-k) +  et-1 (5) • Subtracting (5) from (4), we get Yt = a(1- ) + b0Xt + Yt-1 + vt where vt = et - et-1

  15. Koyck transformation (3) • Why is this transformation useful? • Allows us to take the ad-hoc lag series and condense it into a lagged endogenous variable • now we only lose one observation due to the lagged endogenous variable • the  given by the estimation gives the coefficient of autocorrelation • Problem: by construction, we have first-order autocorrelation • use Durbin h-statistic • but estimating equation might be mis-specified!

  16. Adaptive expectations • Another way to approach the problem of the ad-hoc nature of lags • Can use the example of trying to measure the natural rate of unemployment • In 1968, Friedman estimated the equation: Yt = a + bXt* + ut where Xt* = natural rate of unemployment

  17. Adaptive expectations (2) • Using adaptive expectations we have that Xt* - Xt-1* =  (Xt - Xt-1*) • Can rewrite the equation: Xt* - (1 -  )Xt-1* =  Xt • Using a lag operator where: LXt = Xt-1 L2Xt = Xt-2 where Xt* = expectation Xt = observed 0 <  < 1

  18. Adaptive expectations (3) • We can then rewrite :  Xt = (1 - L )Xt* • where  = (1-  ) • This can be rewritten as: • now we have the natural rate of unemployment in terms of the observed rate of unemployment

  19. Adaptive expectations (3) • Substituting into the model we get: • Upon further multiplication and substitution we arrive at: • this looks very similar to that for the Koyck transformation where

  20. Problems with the approaches • For the lagged endogenous variables in the ad-hoc lag structure, we are uncertain as to which economic model of agent behavior underlies the estimating equation • We have 1st-order autocorrelation by the construction of the model • use the Durbin h-statistic • Yt-1 and et-1 (ut-1) are sure to be correlated [ E(X,e)  0] • this leads to biased estimates • we’ll deal with this using instrumental variables and simultaneous equations

  21. Other topics • Seasonality and the use of dummy variables in time series models. • Trends and their use in time series models • Testing and correcting in the presence of higher orders of serial correlation.

More Related