1 / 72

Comparative Statics: Analysis of Individual Demand and Labor Supply

Comparative Statics: Analysis of Individual Demand and Labor Supply. Chapter 4. Introduction. Rational households are never quite able to find local bliss Ever-changing prices and income require households to continuously adjust their commodity bundle

tory
Télécharger la présentation

Comparative Statics: Analysis of Individual Demand and Labor Supply

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Comparative Statics: Analysis of Individual Demand and Labor Supply Chapter 4

  2. Introduction • Rational households are never quite able to find local bliss • Ever-changing prices and income require households to continuously adjust their commodity bundle • Can study these changes by comparing one equilibrium position to another • Comparative statics analysis • Investigates a change in some parameters holding everything else constant • Called ceteris paribus • With preferences held constant, individual indifference curves remain fixed • Comparative statics is concerned with sensitivity of a solution to changes in parameters • Will derive a household’s demand curve for each commodity

  3. Introduction • Will investigate a change in income, holding all prices constant • Develop Engel curves and Engel’s Law associated with income changes • Based on shapes (slopes) of demand and Engel curves • Commodities are generally classified as normal, luxury, or inferior goods in terms of income change • Ordinary or Giffen goods for price change • Discuss how Slutsky equation considers total effect of a price change as shown to be sum of substitution effect and income effect • Illustrate theoretical possibility of a positively sloping demand curve • Giffen’s Paradox • Discuss use of Slutsky equation to measure compensated price changes and Laspeyres Index to measure Consumer Price Index (CPI) • Extend Slutsky equation to changes in price of another commodity • Develop concepts of gross and net substitutes and gross and net complements

  4. Chapter Objective • To derive a household’s demand functions for commodities it purchases and its labor supply function • Quantity demanded should generally decline as price of a commodity increases • Demand should generally increase with a rise in income • We investigate underlying determinants for this response of quantity demanded

  5. Introduction • Determinants of a household’s supply of labor given a rise in wages may result in supply increasing, declining, or remaining unchanged • Can develop aggregate (market) demand and supply • Market supply and demand functions will provide a foundation for investigating efficient allocation of society’s resources • Applied economists estimate consumer demand and labor supply functions • To determine how responsive consumers and labor are to changes in prices, wages, incomes, sales promotion, and various government programs • Consumer demand is a very large area in economics • Labor economics is also a large area • Impacts of government welfare programs, working conditions, exploitation, and unions

  6. Derived Household Demand • With indifference curves representing preferences and budget lines as income constraints, • Can derive a theoretical relationship between price and a person’s quantity demanded • Consider case of a price change in one of two commodities x1 and x2 • Budget line is • I = p1x1 + p2x2 • Where I, p1, and p2 represent income, per-unit price of commodity 1, and per-unit price of commodity 2, respectively • Figure 4.1 is a graph of budget line • With an x1-intercept of 5 units and an x2-intercept of 10 units

  7. Figure 4.1 Derived demand for a decrease in p1

  8. Derived Household Demand • A household maximizes its utility for a given level of income • At a point on budget line tangent with an indifference curve (commodity bundle A) • Equilibrium bundle (at a given income level and prices) corresponds to one point on household’s demand curve (point a) • Additional points on household’s demand curve for x1 are obtained • By changing price of commodity x1 while holding income and price of x2 constant • For example, decreasing price of x1 from 2 to 1 (p1 = 1) results in budget line tilting outward • With this new price for p1, commodity bundle C represents new equilibrium level of utility maximization

  9. Derived Household Demand • Further changes in p1 will result in additional tangencies of a budget line • With an indifference curve and a corresponding point on household’s demand curve • Connecting points results in household’s demand curve for commodity x1 • Each point on demand curve corresponds with a tangency point between indifference curve and budget line • Household is maximizing utility for a given income level and market price of commodity x1 • Illustrates how much of the commodity a household is willing and able to purchase at a given price • As price of p1 declines household’s MRS(x2 for x1) declines • How much it is willing to pay for an additional unit of x1 also declines • A decline in price results in an increase in a household’s level of utility • Household’s purchasing power has increased as a result of this price decline

  10. Shift in Demand versus a Change in Quantity Demanded • Convenient to graph x1 as a function of its own price • With understanding that income and all other prices are being held constant • As illustrated in Figure 4.1, assuming two commodities and considering a change in p1, then x1 = x1(p1|p2, I) • Where p2 and I are being held constant • By varying p1, price consumption curve traces out locus of tangencies • Between budget line and indifference curve • Negatively sloped demand curve can be derived from this price consumption curve • Decrease in p1 will result in an increase in quantity demanded (a movement along demand curve) • A change in p2 or I will shift demand curve

  11. Shift in Demand versus A Change in Quantity Demanded • Figure 4.2 illustrates difference in a change in quantity demanded versus a shift in demand • At bundle A, a decrease in p2 results in a movement from bundle A to B • Shifts demand curve • Shift depicted as a shift from point a on demand curve x1( p1| p2°, I) to point b on x1( p1| p'2,I ) • A decrease in p1 at bundle A • Results in a movement from bundle A to C • Causes a movement along demand curve x1( p1|p2°, I ) from point a to c • Change in quantity demanded • Change in either of the variables on axes causes a movement along a curve • Whereas change in any factor not on one of the axes causes a shift in curve • For example, a change in income or preferences will shift a demand curve

  12. Inverse Demand Curves • Demand functions depicted in Figures 4.1 and 4.2 are sometimes called inverse demand functions • Dependent variable is on vertical axis and independent variable is on horizontal axis • Price as dependent variable states what level of quantity demanded for a commodity would have to be for household to be willing to pay this price per unit • Inverse demand functions represent price as a function of quantity demanded • As opposed to quantity demanded as a function of price

  13. Figure 4.2 Shift in demand versus change in quantity demanded

  14. Generalizing For K Commodities • In general we can solve for optimal levels of x1*, x2*, … , xk* and * as functions of all parameters (prices and income) • Quantities of x1, x2, … , xk demanded by the household will depend on • Shape of utility function (consumer preferences) • p1, p2, … , pk and I • Demand functions state how much a household is willing and able to consume of a commodity at given prices and income • Mathematically, demand functions are represented as

  15. Homogeneous of Degree Zero Demand Functions • In many developing countries price and income indexing occurs • Due to high rates of inflation • For example, if inflation is running at 10% annually, incomes are automatically adjusted (indexed) upward by 10% • Keeps households’ purchasing power the same • Does not change their demands for commodities • Assuming no money illusion • When all prices and income change proportionately, optimal quantities demanded would remain unchanged • Slope and intercepts of budget constraint do not change • Illustrated in Figure 4.3

  16. Figure 4.3 Homogeneity of demand functions

  17. Homogeneous of Degree Zero Demand Functions • Generally, if prices and income are multiplied by some positive constant a, same budget constraint remains • Given no change in budget constraint from multiplying prices and income by  > 0 • Quantity demanded by a household will also not change • Called homogeneous of degree zero • In this case, consumer demand functions are homogeneous of degree zero in all prices and income. • Household demands are not affected by pure inflation

  18. Numeraire Price • Result of homogeneous of degree zero demand functions • Can divide all prices and income by one of the prices • Demand for a commodity depends on • Price ratios (called relative prices) • Ratio of money income to a price (called real income) • Picking any price, say p1, and multiplying demand function by 1/p1 gives • xj = xj(p1, p2,…, pk, I) = xj(1, p2/p1,…, pk/p1, I/p1) • Where a is 1/p1 • Setting p1 = 1 • Which is relative price to which all other prices and income are compared • Called numeraire price

  19. Changes in Income • A college graduate’s income will generally substantially increase upon landing that first professional job • Results in a change in purchasing power • An increase in income results in an expected increase in purchases • Represented by parallel shifts in budget lines • Only I has changed, so price ratio remains constant • Income consumption path, or income expansion path • Curve intersecting all points where indifference curves are tangent with budget lines (locus of utility-maximizing bundles) • Every point on path represents demanded bundle at that level of income

  20. Engel Curves • From income expansion path, can derive a function that relates income to demand for each commodity at constant prices • Represented by Engel curves as illustrated in Figure 4.4 • As income rises from I1 to I2 and then to I3 • Demand for x1 increases from x11 to x12 and then to x13 • Plotting this increased demand with rise in income yields an Engel curve • Illustrate a relationship between demand for a commodity and income • In Figure 4.4, Engel curve has a positive slope • However Engel curves can have either positive or negative slopes • Positively sloped Engel curves are called normal goods • An increase in income results in more of commodity being purchased

  21. Figure 4.4 Income expansion path and Engel curve …

  22. Homothetic Preferences • If income expansion paths, and thus each Engel curve, are straight lines (linear) through origin • Household will consume same proportion of each commodity at every level of income • Assumes prices are held fixed • Homothetic preferences • Preferences resulting in consuming same proportion of commodities as income increases • Commodities are scaled up and down in same proportion as income changes

  23. Luxury and Necessary Goods • Can further divide normal goods into luxury and necessary goods • If income expansion path bends toward one commodity or the other • Figure 4.5 illustrates income expansion path bending toward commodity x1 • Making x1 a luxury good • x1 is a luxury good if (x1/I)I/x1 > 1 • As income increases, household spends proportionally more of its income on x1 • Examples: fine wines and silk suits • Necessary good • If, as income increases, household spends proportionally less of its income on a commodity • Examples are gasoline and textbooks

  24. Figure 4.5 Income expansion path and Engel curve for a luxury good, x1

  25. Luxury and Necessary Goods • As household receives more income, it wishes to consume more of both types of commodities • But proportionally more of luxury good than of necessary good • For two-commodity case, if one commodity is a luxury good • Other must be a necessary good

  26. Inferior Goods • Negatively sloped Engel curve is associated with a backward-bending income expansion path • With an increase in income, a household actually wants to consume less of one of the commodities • In Figure 4.6, as income increases • Consumption of x1 declines • Called an inferior good and is defined as x1/I < 0 • Examples include cheap wine and used books

  27. Figure 4.6 Income expansion path and Engel curve for an inferior good x1

  28. Engel’s Law • Relationship between income and consumption of specific items has been studied since 18th century • Engel was first to conduct such studies • Developed generalization about consumer behavior • Proportion of total expenditure devoted to food declines as income rises • Has been verified in numerous subsequent studies • Engel’s Law appears to be such a consistent empirical finding that some economists have suggested proportion of income spent on food might be used as an indicator of poverty • Families that spend more than say 40% of their income on food might be regarded as poor

  29. Changes in Price • If p1 is allowed to vary holding p2 and I fixed, budget line will tilt • Illustrated in Figure 4.7 • Locus of tangencies will sweep out a price consumption curve • Curve connecting all tangencies between indifference curves and budget lines for alternative price levels

  30. Figure 4.7 Price consumption curve and demand curve …

  31. Ordinary Goods • Price consumption curve for an ordinary good is illustrated in Figure 4.7 • Where xj ÷ pj < 0 defines an ordinary good • Demand curve derived from price consumption curve has a negative slope • Indicates inverse relationship between a commodity’s own price and quantity consumed

  32. Giffen Goods • Slope of a demand curve could be positive • xj ÷ pj > 0 • Defines a Giffen good • Decrease in p1 results in a decrease in demand for x1 • Shown in Figure 4.8

  33. Figure 4.8 Price consumption curve for a Giffen good

  34. Substitution and Income Effects • Determinants of whether a commodity is ordinary good or Giffen good • Depend on direction and magnitude of substitution and income effects • Figure 4.9 shows effects for case of an own price change where p1 decreases • Initial budget constraint • I = p1x1 + p2x2 • New budget constraint • I = p‘1x1 + p2x2 • Where p'1 < p°1 • Price decrease in p1 results in increased quantity demanded of x1 • Shown in Figure 4.9 • Increase in quantity demanded is total effect of price decline • Total effect = x1/p1 < 0 • Can be decomposed into substitution and income effects

  35. Figure 4.9 Substitution and income effects …

  36. Substitution Effect • In 2002, automobiles in Canada generally cost from 20% to 35% less than in US • With fall of trade barriers and harmonizing of environmental and safety regulations • Only major differences between new cars made for sale in Canada and those made for sale in U.S. • Speedometers and odometers

  37. Substitution Effect • U.S. automobile buyers attempt to substitute Canadian cars for U.S. ones • Illustrates substitution effect (also called Hicksian substitution) • As an incentive for consumers to purchase more of a lower-priced commodity (Canadian cars) and less of a higher-priced commodity (U.S. cars) • Given a change in price of one commodity relative to another • To determine substitution effect • Hold level of utility constant at initial utility level, U° • Consider price change for x1 • If a household were to stay on same indifference curve • Consumption patterns would be allocated to equate MRS to new price ratio

  38. Substitution Effect • Represented in Figure 4.9 by a budget line parallel to new budget line • But tangent to initial indifference curve • Point B, illustrates a household’s equilibrium for a level of utility U° with p1' as the price of x1 • Bundle A represents consumer equilibrium for the same level of utility as bundle B • Decrease in p1 results in consumer purchasing more of x1 and less of x2 with level of utility unchanged • Movement from bundle A to bundle B is substitution effect

  39. Compensated Law of Demand • In Figure 4.9, Strict Convexity Axiom makes it impossible for a tangency point representing the new price ratio (bundle B) to occur left of bundle A • If p1 decreases, implying p1/p2 decreasing • MRS also decreases • Only way for MRS to decrease is for x1 to increase and x2 to decrease • Thus, decreasing x1’s own price holding utility constant results in • Consumption of x1 increasing • Own substitution effect is always negative • Implying x1/p1|dU=0 < 0 • Known as Compensated Law of Demand • Where price and quantity always move in opposite directions for a constant level of utility

  40. Income Effect • In general, a change in the price of a commodity a household purchases changes purchasing power of household’s income • Called income effect • For example, an increase in price of prescription drugs decreases ability to purchase both drugs and food • Decreased ability to purchase same level of commodities represents a decline in purchasing power • Has same effect as if household experienced a change in income • A price decline has effect of increasing a household’s purchasing power or real income

  41. Income Effect • Figure 4.9 illustrates a price decline of p1 with utility remaining constant • Results in an increase in real income or purchasing power • Represented by a parallel outward shift in budget line associated with the new price • Equilibrium tangency shifts from point B to C, which is the measurement of the income effect • Mathematically, given the budget constraint I = p1x1 + p2x2 • Change in income from a change in p1, holding consumption of commodities x1 and x2 constant, is • I/p1 = x1 • Substitution effect will equal total effect if, given a decline in p1, income also falls by x1 • If income is not reduced, then this decline in p1 represents an increase in real income • Specifically, a decline in p1 results in an increase in IR of x1 • I/p1 = -x1 • Minus sign results from condition that a change in price and a change in real income move in opposite directions

  42. Income Effect • Change in real income depends on how much x1 a household is consuming • If purchases of x1 are small, impact of a price change will be minor • Partial derivative x1/I may be either positive (normal good) or negative (inferior good) • Sign of income effect is indeterminate

  43. Slutsky Equation • Combining equations for substitution and income effects yields • Called Slutsky equation • Mathematically defines substitution and income effects • Sum is total effect of a price change • Total effect is a movement from bundle A to bundle C or a movement along demand curve for a change in p1 (Figure 4.9) • Substitution effect defines a change in slope of budget line • Would motivate a household to choose bundle B if choices had been confined to those on original indifference curve • Income effect defines movement from B to C resulting from a change in purchasing power • p1 decreases • Implies an increase in real income

  44. Slutsky Equation • If x1 is a normal good, a household will demand more of it in response to increase in purchasing power • Own substitution effect always holds • x1/p1|U=constant < 0 • Normal good results in a negative income and negative substitution effect • Total effect is sum of these two negative effects, so it also is negative • x1/p1 < 0, an ordinary good • Known as Law of Demand • Demand for a commodity will always decrease when its price increases • If demand increases with an increase in income

  45. Slutsky Equation • Figure 4.10 represents income and substitution effects for a price increase in commodity x1 • Results in an inward tilt of budget line with a new equilibrium tangency point C • Substitution effect represents price increase holding level of utility constant • Bundle B is a tangency of a budget line, given new increase in price, with initial indifference curve • Movement from bundle A to bundle B is substitution effect • Increase in price of p1 results in a decrease in purchasing power or real income • Income effect measuring this decrease in real income is represented by a parallel leftward shift in budget line • Income effect is negative and reinforces negative substitution effect • Total effect is sum of substitution and income effect representing a movement from A to C

  46. Figure 4.10 Substitution and income effects for an increase in p1

  47. Slutsky Equation • Not all commodities are normal goods • Some commodities are inferior • Rise in income will yield a decrease in their consumption • Income effect is positive • Will partially or completely offset substitution effect • If income effect does not completely offset negative substitution effect • Total effect will still be negative

  48. Slutsky Equation • Figure 4.11 illustrates these effects for inferior and ordinary goods • Movement from A to B is substitution effect • Decline in price results in an increase in consumption of x1 holding utility constant • Illustrates negative substitution effect • Income effect, movement from B to C, partially offsets negative substitution effect • If this positive income effect does not completely offset negative substitution effect, total effect is still negative • Results in an ordinary but inferior good

  49. Figure 4.11 Substitution and income effects for an inferior and ordinary good, x1

  50. Giffen’s Paradox • If x1 is an inferior good • Sign of total effect can be either positive or negative • Substitution effect is negative and income effect is positive • Positive income effect can be large enough to produce result illustrated in Figure 4.12 • Demand curve has a positive slope • Increase in price results in an increase in quantity demanded • English applied economist Robert Giffen claims to have observed effect in 19th-century Ireland • An increase in price of potatoes resulted in an increase in consumption of potatoes

More Related