1 / 27

Introducing NERSA’s Inclining Block Tariffs (IBT’s)

Introducing NERSA’s Inclining Block Tariffs (IBT’s). Topics to be covered. Introduction of the NERSA delegate Mandate Purpose of the visit Background Introduction of IBTs Key Design Principles Development of IBTs Information Requirements Determination of the IBTs Challenges Myths

cecil
Télécharger la présentation

Introducing NERSA’s Inclining Block Tariffs (IBT’s)

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Introducing NERSA’s Inclining Block Tariffs (IBT’s)

  2. Topics to be covered • Introduction of the NERSA delegate • Mandate • Purpose of the visit • Background • Introduction of IBTs • Key Design Principles • Development of IBTs • Information Requirements • Determination of the IBTs • Challenges • Myths • Advantages • Questions and Discussions

  3. NERSA’s PROFILE AND MANDATE The National Energy Regulator of South Africa (NERSA) is a regulatory authority established as a juristic person in Terms of Section 3 of the National Energy Regulator Act, 2004 (Act No.40 of 2004). NERSA’s mandate is to regulate the electricity, piped-gas and petroleum pipelines in terms of the Electricity Regulation Act, 2006(Act No.4 of 2006), Gas Act, 2001(Act No.48 of 2001)and the Petroleum Pipelines Act, 2003(Act No.60 of 2003) and the Petroleum Pipelines Levies Act, 2004 (Act No.28 of 2004) In terms of Section 4(a)(ii) of the Electricity Regulation Act (Act No.4 of 2006) “the Regulator must regulate prices and tariffs.” In the approval of the prices and tariffs, the Energy Regulator enables an efficient licensee to recover the full costs of its licensed activities, including a reasonable return or margin

  4. The NERSA delegation * These analysts are responsible for analysis of municipal tariff applications for RED 3

  5. PURPOSE “To share the information regarding the IBTs and for by municipalities to share the challenges being experienced with regards to the implementation of IBTs to enable NERSA to assist.”

  6. BACKGROUND • During the stakeholder consultation on the Eskom interim price increase application (early 2009), many stakeholders called for the introduction of “pro-poor” tariffs with some even suggesting the introduction of IBTs • Furthermore, the mandate for the introduction of IBTs comes the Electricity Pricing Policy of the Government. This policy reads as:“Low income tariff customer tariff subsidization: Charging an appropriate tariff structure that allows for maximum subsidisation at low consumption levels with gradually reducing cross-subsidies as the consumption levels increase.”

  7. BACKGROUND (Cont) • On 25 June 2010, NERSA approved a 31.3% price increase for Eskom for 2009/10 (interim application) and further limited the increase to the poor to 15%. This method of protecting the poor (differentiated pricing) was introduced by NERSA in 2008/09. • The abovementioned decision was stated as follows: “The approved price increase on the average standard tariffs includes a limited price increase of 15% to both Eskom and municipalities’ poor customers (i.e. Homelight 1 & 2 tariffs). It must be noted that this is an interim measure until the implementation of inclining block rate tariffs for protection of the poor. The full implementation will occur in the Multi-Year price Determination 2 (MYPD2).”

  8. BACKGROUND (Cont) • During the analysis of the MYPD2 application NERSA investigated various options of providing protection to low-income tariff customers. The table below highlights these options:

  9. BACKGROUND (Cont) • During this process, NERSA commenced with an international benchmark study on the design of an IBT • During this study it was found that an IBT rate structure would allow NERSA to achieve the objective of (1) protecting low-income tariff customers and (2) promoting energy efficiency. This would also allow for compliance with the EPP. • For these reasons, the IBT was selected as the most preferred and viable option • On 24 February 2010, the Energy Regulator approved the implementation of IBTs concurrently with the 2010/11 price increase, in order to provide for cross-subsidies for low income domestic customers, as required by the Electricity Pricing Policy (EPP)

  10. INTRODUCTION What is an IBT? • An Inclining Block Tariff is a tariff structure where the customers’ consumption is divided into blocks. Each block has a price per unit of energy consumed; which increases with each succeeding block i.e. it consists of different prices for different energy consumption levels. For example: a low block rate for the first 100kWh of consumption and a higher block rate for the balance of consumption N.B It must be noted that the IBT is only applicable for residential/domestic customers (for now)

  11. ILLUSTRATIVE EXAMPLE Block 4 >600kWh 88.0c/kWh Block 3 351 – 600kWh 74.0c/kWh Block 2 51 – 350kWh 58.0c/kWh Block 1 0 – 50kWk 54.0c/kWh

  12. ILLUSTRATIVE EXAMPLE (Cont) • Example: Thabo consumes 650kWh/month. In 2009/10 the tariff applicable to him is 73.0c/kWh. His monthly bill is therefore R474.50. In month 1 of 2010/11 he again consumes 650kWh. This time he is charged according to the IBT rates as follows:

  13. ILLUSTRATIVE EXAMPLE (Cont) • This example illustrates that the IBT is based on the principle of incremental pricing i.e. the user is charged incrementally on the block rates as consumption increases. This is similar to the progressive tax system • Therefore if Thabo reduces his consumption by 50kWh – his bill will reduce to R386.00 • Now what if Ntombi consumes consumes 1200 kWh • Her bill on the previous standard rate of 73 c/kWh • R876.00: Average 73 c/kWh • Her bill on the IBT structure • R914.00: Average 76.17 c/kWh

  14. KEY DESIGN PRINCIPLES • The need to be easy and economical to implement/ administer • The need to ensure stability, simplicity and understandability and transparency • The need to utilize appropriate metering and supply technology • The customer’s ability to pay • Equity: preserving a degree of cross-subsidies to ensure support to low income customers • The requirement to shield the poor from the impact of unacceptably high price increases • The need to ensure revenue neutrality to the utility

  15. DEVELOPMENT OF IBTs • The number of blocks and consumption levels were determined as per the table below for both Eskom and municipalities. The tariff was limited to 4 blocks in keeping with the design principle of being easy and economical to implement.

  16. DEVELOPMENT OF IBTs (Cont) • The “basis for the price increase” resulted in the tariff benchmark levels as illustrated in the next 2 slides. • For 2010/11 two sets of benchmarks (19% and 22%) are applicable. The “19% guideline” refers to municipalities who implemented 34% in 2009/10. The “22% guideline” refers to municipalities who implemented 25%.

  17. DEVELOPMENT OF IBTs (Cont) 19% Benchmark Levels 22% Benchmark Levels

  18. INFORMATION REQUIREMENTS • In order to assess the IBT structure the following data/ information is required from the municipalities: • Proposed block energy rate tariffs for the 4 blocks in accordance with the benchmarks • Proposed fixed charge • Customer numbers as per existing domestic tariff categories together with the related consumption • Provide details regarding impact on revenues and calculations thereof

  19. DETERMINATION OF IBT’sConventional Meters • The IBTs are assessed for the domestic high and domestic low tariff categories. The domestic low is based on the average consumption of 400kWh and domestic high on the average consumption of 800kWh. The IBTs are determined as follows: • Test 1: Comparison of the energy rates to the NERSA approved benchmarks in order to assess the proposed IBT energy rates. • Test 2: Compare weighted average tariff to guideline increase – For the domestic high category, the proposed fixed charges of the municipality is added to the average energy rate. This results in an average tariff rate after the fixed charges.

  20. DETERMINATION OF IBTs (Cont)Conventional Meters • Test 3: Revenue Protection: The final test is to ensure that the introduction of IBTs does not result in unintended revenue losses or windfall gains. The 2009/10 domestic residential revenues are compared to the revenues achieved with the IBTs to ensure that this result is achieved. • Where introduction of the IBT’s results in a shortfall for the municipality, a revenue allowance protection is built in to ensure that the shortfall in revenues does not occur.

  21. DETERMINATION OF IBTsPrepaid Meters • WEIGHTED AVERAGE INCREASES • For municipalities that are unable to implement IBTs, a weighted average increase is calculated. This is mostly utilised for the prepaid tariff categories due to system challenges. • The weighted average is calculated using the customer’s monthly bill at the previous year’s bill (2009/10 tariff) compared with the estimated average monthly bill calculated based on block rates for 2010/11 financial year • Note: There must be significant and compelling reasons provided by the municipality as to why IBTs cannot be implemented (especially for conventional metered customers) before NERSA considers the calculation of the weighted average increases.

  22. CALCULATION OF IBT EXAMPLE: PROPOSAL BY MUNIC

  23. CALCULATION OF IBT EXAMPLE: WITH REVENUE PROTECTION

  24. CHALLENGES

  25. MYTHS • Municipalities believe that implementation of IBTs will result in revenue losses. However, it is evident (from previous slides - examples) that the IBTs are structured to ensure revenue protection (revenue protection fee) • NERSA is not approving tariffs of municipalities that are not implementing IBTs. For municipalities that are unable to implement IBTs, NERSA is considering the implementation of weighted average increases. No application has been rejected on the basis of non-implementation of IBTS.

  26. ADVANTAGES • In the past (2008/09 and 2009/10) NERSA limited the increases to the domestic low customers (last year the increase was limited to15%). This resulted in revenue losses for municipalities – especially municipalities with a predominantly domestic customer base. • The IBTs ensures the revenue protection of the municipality and it is therefore considered a optimum method of protecting low-income tariff customers whilst also ensuring the sustainability of the municipality. THE END !

  27. Feel it, it is here!!!

More Related