1 / 31

SECOND PART on AGT: Algorithmic Mechanism Design

SECOND PART on AGT: Algorithmic Mechanism Design. The implementation problem.

elpida
Télécharger la présentation

SECOND PART on AGT: Algorithmic Mechanism Design

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. SECOND PART on AGT: Algorithmic Mechanism Design

  2. The implementation problem Imagine you are a planner who develops criteria for social welfare, and you want to design a game (interaction among individuals, i.e., players) such that the equilibrium of the game (i.e., its outcome) conforms to some concept of social optimality (i.e., aggregation of players’ preferences w.r.t. to a certain outcome). Since these preferences of individuals are private, you have to disclose them in order to precisely evaluate the social utility of a certain outcome. However, it may be in the best interest of some agent to lie about its preferences. Indeed, this may lead to a certain outcome which improves its personal benefit, regardless if this may negatively affect other agents! Thus, in this strategic setting, which techniques can be used to convince players to cooperate honestly with the system?

  3. The implementation problem (2) • Given: • An economic system comprising of self-interested, rational players, which hold some secret information • A system-wide goal (social-choice function) • Question: • Does there exist a mechanism that can enforce (through suitable economic incentives) the players to behave in such a way that the desired goal is implemented (i.e., the outcome of the interaction is an equilibrium in which the s.c.f., obtained as an aggregation of players’ preferences, is optimized)?

  4. Designing a Mechanism • Informally, designing a mechanism means to define a game in which a desired outcome must be reached (in equilibrium) • However, games induced by mechanisms are different from games seen so far: • Players hold independent private values • The payoff are a function of these types  each player doesn’t really know about the other players’ payoffs, but only about its one!  Games with incomplete information

  5. Social-choice function: the winner should be the guy having in mind the highest value for the painting An example: sealed-bid auctions t1=10 r1=11 ri: is the amount of money player i bids (in a sealed envelope) for the painting t2=12 r2=10 t3=7 r3=7 • The mechanism tells to players: • How the item will be allocated (i.e., who will be the winner), depending on the received bids • (2) The payment the winner has to return, as a function of the received bids ti: is the maximum amount of money player i is willing to pay for the painting If player i wins and has to pay p then its utility is ui=ti-p, otherwise it is 0

  6. A simple mechanism: no payment t1=10 r1=+ ?!? t2=12 r2=+ t3=7 r3=+ Mechanism: The highest bid wins and the price of the item is 0 …it doesn’t work…

  7. Another simple mechanism: pay your bid Is it the right choice? t1=10 The winner is player 1 and he’ll pay 9 r1=9 t2=12 r2=8 t3=7 r3=6 Mechanism: The highest bid wins and the winner will pay his bid Player i may bid ri< ti (in this way he is guaranteed not to incur a negative utility) …and so the winner could be the wrong one… …it doesn’t work…

  8. An elegant solution: Vickrey’s second price auction I know they are not lying t1=10 The winner is player 2 and he’ll pay 10 r1=10 t2=12 r2=12 t3=7 r3=7 Mechanism: The highest bid wins and the winner will pay the second highest bid every player has convenience to declare the truth! (we prove it in the next slide)

  9. Theorem In the Vickrey auction, for every player i, ri=ti is a dominant strategy Fix i and ti, and look at strategies for player i. Let R= maxji {rj} proof Caseti ≥ R (observe that R is unknown to player i) declaring ri=ti gives utility ui= ti-R ≥ 0 (player wins ifti> R, while if ti= Rthen player can either win or lose, depending on the tie-breaking rule, but its utility in this case is always 0) declaring any ri > R,ri≠ti, yields again utility ui= ti-R ≥ 0 (player wins) declaring any ri < R yields ui=0 (player loses) Caseti< R declaring ri=tiyields utility ui= 0 (player loses) declaring any ri < R,ri≠ti, yields again utility ui= 0 (player loses) declaring any ri> R yields ui=ti-R < 0 (player wins)  In all the cases, reporting a false type produces a not better utility, and so telling the truth is a dominant strategy!

  10. Mechanism Design Problem: ingredients • N players; each player i, i=1,..,N, has some private information tiTi (actually, the only private info) called type • Vickrey’s auction: the type is the value of the painting that a player has in mind, and so Ti is the set of positive real numbers • A set of feasible outcomesX (i.e., the result of the interaction of the players with the mechanism) • Vickrey’s auction: X is the set of players (indeed an outcome of the auction is a winner of it, i.e., a player)

  11. Mechanism Design Problem: ingredients (2) • For each vector of types t=(t1, t2, …, tN), and for each feasible outcome xX, a social-choice functionf(t,x)that measures the quality of x as a function of t. This is the function that the mechanism aims to implement (i.e., it aims to select an outcome x* that minimizes/maximizes it, but the problem is that types are unknown!) • Vickrey’s auction: f(t,x)is the type associated with a feasible winner x (i.e., any player), and the objective is to maximize f, i.e., to allocate the painting to the bidder with highest type • Each player has a strategy spaceSi and performs a strategic action; we restrict ourselves to direct revelation mechanisms, in which the action is reporting a valueri from the type space (with possibly ri ti), i.e., Si =Ti • Vickrey’s auction: the action is to bid a value ri

  12. Mechanism Design Problem: ingredients (3) • For each feasible outcome xX, each player makes a valuationvi(ti,x) (in terms of some common currency), expressing its preference about that output x • Vickrey’s auction: if player i wins the auction then its valuation is equal to its typeti, otherwise it is 0 • For each feasible outcome xX, each player receives a payment pi(x) by the system in terms of the common currency (a negative payment means that the agent makes a payment to the system); payments are used by the system to incentive players to be collaborative. • Vickrey’s auction: if player i wins the auction then he makes a payment equal to -rj, where rj is the second highest bid, otherwise it is 0 • Then, for each feasible outcome xX, the utility of player i (in terms of the common currency) coming from outcome x will be: ui(ti,x) = pi(x) + vi(ti,x) • Vickrey’s auction: if player i wins the auction then its utility is equal to ui = -rj+ti ≥ 0, where rj is the second highest bid, otherwise it is ui = 0+0=0

  13. Mechanism Design Problem: the goal Given all the above ingredients, design a mechanismM=<g(r), p(x)>, where: • g(r) is an algorithm which computes an outcome x=x(r)Xas a function of the reported typesr • p(x)=(p1,…,pN) is a paymentscheme w.r.t. outcome x that specifies a payment for each player which implements the social-choice function f(t,x)in equilibrium w.r.t. players’ utilities (according to a given solution concept, e.g., dominant strategy equilibrium, Nash equilibrium, etc.). (In other words, there exists a reported type vector r* for which the mechanism provides a solution x(r*) and a payment scheme p(x(r*)) such that players’ utilities ui(ti, x(r*)) = pi(x(r*)) + vi(ti, x(r*)) are in equilibrium, and f(t, x(r*)) is optimal (either minimum or maximum))

  14. Mechanism Design: a picture Output which should implement the social choice function in equilibrium w.r.t. players’ utilities System Private “types” Reported types “I propose to you the following mechanism M=<g(r), p(x)>” t1 r1 p1 player 1 tN rN pN player N Payments Each player reports strategicallyto maximize its well-being… …in response to a payment which is a function of the output!

  15. Implementation with dominant strategies Def.: A mechanism is an implementation with dominant strategies if the s.c.f. f(t,x) is implemented in dominant strategy equilibrium, i.e., there exists a reported type vector r*=(r1*, r2*, …, rN*) such that: • for each player i and for each reported type vector r =(r1, r2, …, rN), it holds: ui(ti,x(r-i,ri*)) ≥ ui(ti,x(r)) where x(r-i,ri*)=x(r1, …, ri-1, ri*, ri+1,…, rN); • f(t,x(r*)) is optimized.

  16. Strategy-Proof Mechanisms • If truth telling is the dominant strategy in a mechanism then this is called Strategy-Proof ortruthful r*=t, and so players report their true types instead of strategically manipulating it, and the algorithm of the mechanism runs on the true input • Strategy-proof mechanisms are very desirable from a system-wide point of view, since they disclose the true preferences of individuals. Notice, however, that f(t,x) could be also implemented in non-truthful dominant strategy. However, the revelation principle states that if there exists such an implementation, then there exists a truthful implementation as well.

  17. Truthful Mechanism Design: Economics Issues QUESTION: How to design a truthful mechanism? Or, in other words: • How to design g(r), and • How to define the payment scheme p in such a way that the underlying social-choice function is implemented truthfully? Under which conditions can this be done?

  18. A prominent class of problems • Utilitarian problems: A problem is utilitarian if its social-choice function is such that f(t,x) =i vi(ti,x), i.e.,the s.c.f. is separately-additive w.r.t. players’ valuations. • Remark 1: the auction problem is utilitarian, in that f(t,x)is the type associated with the winner x, and the valuation of a player is either its type or 0, depending on whether it wins or not. Then, f(t,x) =i vi(ti,x). • Remark 2: in many network optimization problems the s.c.f. is separately-additive Good news: for utilitarian problems there is a class of truthful mechanisms 

  19. Vickrey-Clarke-Groves (VCG) Mechanisms • A VCG-mechanism is (the only) strategy-proof mechanism for utilitarianproblems: • Algorithm g(r) computes: x = arg maxyXi vi(ri,y) • Payment function for player i: pi (x) = hi(r-i) +j≠i vj(rj,x) wherehi(r-i) is an arbitrary function of the types reported by players other than player i. • What about non-utilitarian problems? Strategy-proof mechanisms are known only when the type is a single parameter.

  20. Theorem VCG-mechanisms are truthful for utilitarian problems proof Fix i, r-i, ti. Let ř=(r-i,ti) and consider a strategy riti x=g(r-i,ti) =g(ř) x’=g(r-i,ri) + jvj(řj,x) [hi(r-i) + jivj(rj,x)] + vi(ti,x) = hi(r-i) ui(ti,x) = ui(ti,x’) = + jvj(řj,x’) [hi(r-i) + jivj(rj,x’)] + vi(ti,x’) = hi(r-i) • but x is an optimal solution w.r.t. ř =(r-i,ti), i.e., • x = arg maxyXi vi(ř,y) ui(ti,x)  ui(ti,x’). jvj(řj,x) ≥ jvj(řj,x’)

  21. How to define hi(r-i)? Remark: not all functions make sense. For instance, what happens in our example of the Vickrey auction if we set for every player hi(r-i)=-1000 (notice this is independent of reported value ri of player i, and so it obeys the definition)? Answer: It happens that players’ utility become negative; more precisely, the winner’s utility is ui(ti,x) = pi(x) + vi(ti,x) = hi(r-i) +j≠i vj(rj,x) + vi(ti,x) = -1000+0+12 = -988 while utility of losers is ui(ti,x) = pi(x) + vi(ti,x) = hi(r-i) +j≠i vj(rj,x) + vi(ti,x) = -1000+12+0 = -988 This is undesirable in reality, since with such perspective players would not partecipate to the auction!

  22. The Clarke payments solution maximizing the sum of valuations when player i doesn’t play • This is a special VCG-mechanism in which hi(r-i) = -j≠i vj(rj,x(r-i)) • pi(x) = -j≠i vj(rj,x(r-i)) +j≠i vj(rj,x) • With Clarke payments, one can prove that players’ utility are always non-negative  players are interested in playing the game

  23. The Vickrey’s auction is a VCG mechanism with Clarke payments • Recall that auctions are utilitarian problem. Then, the VCG-mechanism associated with the Vickrey’s auction is: • x = arg maxyXi vi(ri,y) …this is equivalent to allocate to the bidder with highest reported cost (in the end, the highest type, since it is strategy-proof) • pi = -j≠i vj(rj,x(r-i)) +j≠i vj(rj,x) …this is equivalent to say that the winner pays the second highest offer, and the losers pay 0, respectively Remark: the difference between the second highest offer and the highest offer is unbounded (frugality issue)

  24. VCG-Mechanisms: Advantages • For System Designer: • The goal, i.e., the optimization of the social-choice function, is achieved with certainty • For players: • players have truth telling as the dominant strategy, so they need not require any computational systems to deliberate about other players strategies

  25. VCG-Mechanisms: Disadvantages • For System Designer: • The payments may be sub-optimal (frugality) • Apparently, with Clarke payments, the system may need to run the mechanism’s algorithm N+1 times: once with all players (for computing the outcome x), and once for every player (for computing the associated payment)  If the problem is hard to solve then the computational cost may be very heavy • For players: • players may not like to tell the truth to the system designer as it can be used in other ways

  26. Mechanism Design: Algorithmic Issues QUESTION: What is the time complexity of the mechanism? Or, in other words: • What is the time complexity of g(r)? • What is the time complexity to calculate the N payment functions? • What does it happen if it is NP-hard to implement the underlying social-choice function? Question: What is the time complexity of the Vickrey auction? Answer:Θ(N), where N is the number of players. Indeed, it suffices to check all the offers, by keeping track of the lowest one and second lowest one.

  27. Algorithmic mechanism design and network protocols • Large networks (e.g., Internet) are built and controlled by diverse and competitive entities: • Entities own different components of the network and hold private information • Entities are selfish and have different preferences  Mechanism design is a useful tool to design protocols working in such an environment, but time complexity is an important issue due to the massive network size

  28. Algorithmic mechanism design for network optimization problems • Simplifying the Internet model, we assume that each player owns a single edge of a graph G=(V,E), and privately knows the cost for using it  Classic optimization problems on G become mechanism design optimization problems in which the player’s type is the weight of the edge! • Many basic network design problems have been studied in this framework: shortest path (SP), single-source shortest paths tree (SPT), minimum spanning tree (MST), and many others • Remark: Quite naturally, SP and MST are utilitarian problems (indeed the cost of a solution is simply the sum of the edge costs), while the SPT is not! Can you see why?

  29. Some remarks • In general, network optimization problems are minimization problems (the Vickrey’s auction was instead a maximization problem) • Accordingly, we have: • for each xX, the valuation function vi(ti,x) represents a cost incurred by player i in the solution x (and so it is a negative function of its type) • the social-choice function f(t,x) is negative (since it is an “aggregation” of negative functions), and so its maximization corresponds to a minimization of the negation of the valuation functions (i.e., a minimization of the aggregation of the costs incurred by the players) • payments are now from the mechanism to players (i.e., they are positive)

  30. Summary of main results  For all these basic problems, the time complexity of the mechanism equals that of the canonical centralized algorithm!

  31. Exercise: redefine the Vickrey auction in the minimization version I want to allocate the job to the true cheapest machine The winner is machine 3 and it will receive 10 t1=10 r1=10 t2=12 job to be allocated to machines r2=12 t3=7 r3=7 Once again, the second price auction works: the cheapest bid wins and the winner will get the second cheapest bid ti: cost incurred by i if he does the job if machine i is selected and receives a payment of p its utility is p-ti

More Related