1 / 73

Chapter 5

Chapter 5. Production. © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western. Production Functions. The purpose of a firm is to turn inputs into outputs. An abstract model of production is the production function , a mathematical relationship between inputs and outputs. Production Functions.

glen
Télécharger la présentation

Chapter 5

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Chapter 5 Production © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

  2. Production Functions • The purpose of a firm is to turn inputs into outputs. • An abstract model of production is the production function, a mathematical relationship between inputs and outputs.

  3. Production Functions • Letting q represent the output of a particular good during a period, K represent capital use, L represent labor input, and M represent raw materials, the following equation represents a production function.

  4. Two-Input Production Function • An important question is how firms choose their levels of output and inputs. • While the choices of inputs will obviously vary with the type of firm, a simplifying assumption is often made that the firm uses two inputs, labor and capital.

  5. Application 5.1: Everyone is a Firm • Looking at people as “firms can yield some interesting insights • Economists have tried to estimate the amount of production that people do for themselves. • Time-use studies suggest that the time people spend in home production is only slightly less than the time spent working.

  6. Application 5.1: Everyone is a Firm • Some of the more straightforward things produced at home are what might be called “housing services”. • The production function concept is widely used in thinking about health issues. • A somewhat more far-fetched application of the home-production concept is to view families as “producers of children.”

  7. Marginal Product • Marginal physical productivity, or more simply, the marginal product of an input is the additional output that can be produced by adding one more unit of a particular input while holding all other inputs constant. • The marginal product of labor (MPL) is the extra output obtained by employing one more unit of labor while holding the level of capital equipment constant.

  8. Marginal Product • The marginal product of capital (MPK) is the extra output obtained by using one more machine while holding the number of workers constant.

  9. Diminishing Marginal Product • It is expected that the marginal product of an input will depend upon the level of the input used. • Since, holding capital constant, production of more output is likely to eventually decline with adding more labor, it is expected that marginal product will eventually diminish as shown in Figure 5.1.

  10. FIGURE 5.1: Relationship between Output and Labor Input Holding Other Inputs Constant Output Total per week Output L* Labor input per week (a) Total output MP L L* Labor input per week (b) Marginal product

  11. Diminishing Marginal Product • The top panel of Figure 5.1 shows the relationship between output per week and labor input during the week as capital is held fixed. • Initially, output increases rapidly as new workers are added, but eventually it diminishes as the fixed capital becomes overutilized.

  12. Marginal Product Curve • The marginal product curve is simply the slope of the total product curve. • The declining slope, as shown in panel b, shows diminishing marginal productivity.

  13. Average Product • Average product is simply “output per worker” calculated by dividing total output by the number of workers used to produce the output. • This corresponds to what many people mean when they discuss productivity, but economists emphasize the change in output reflected in the marginal product.

  14. Appraising the Marginal Product Concept • Marginal product requires the ceteris paribus assumption that other things, such as the level of other inputs and the firm’s technical knowledge, are held constant. • An alternative way, that is more realistic, is to study the entire production function for a good.

  15. APPLICATION 5.2: Why Do the Japanese Have a Cost Advantage in Making Cars? • In 1979 Japan overtook the United States as the world’s largest producer of automobiles. • Japan appears to have a productivity advantage. • For example, workers at Honda or Toyota take about 30 hours to produce a car while workers in General Motors or Chrysler take about 45 hours.

  16. APPLICATION 5.2: Why Do the Japanese Have a Cost Advantage in Making Cars? • Reasons for this are not known although it does not appear to be explained by simple substitution of capital for labor. • U.S. producers tend to use more assembly lines which allows greater variability in vehicle size than in Japan. • This makes it easier to use automating production, such as robots, in Japan.

  17. APPLICATION 5.2: Why Do the Japanese Have a Cost Advantage in Making Cars? • Also, although both U.S. and Japanese producers tend to buy many components of cars from independent suppliers, these suppliers are better integrated with the assembly firms in Japan. • In addition, there appears to be more of an adversarial relationship between labor and management in the U.S. than in Japan.

  18. Isoquant Maps • An isoquant is a curve that shows the various combinations of inputs that will produce the same (a particular) amount of output. • An isoquant map is a contour map of a firm’s production function. • All of the isoquants from a production function are part of this isoquant map.

  19. Isoquant Map • In Figure 5.2, the firm is assumed to use the production function, q = f(K,L) to produce a single good. • The curve labeled q = 10 is an isoquant that shows various combinations of labor and capital, such as points A and B, that produce exactly 10 units of output per period.

  20. FIGURE 5.2: Isoquant Map Capital per week KA A KB B q = 10 0 Labor per week LA LB

  21. Isoquant Map • The isoquants labeled q = 20 and q = 30 represent two more of the infinite curves that represent different levels of output. • Isoquants record successively higher levels of output the farther away from the origin they are in a northeasterly direction.

  22. FIGURE 5.2: Isoquant Map Capital per week KA A q = 30 q = 20 KB B q = 10 0 Labor per week LA LB

  23. Isoquant Map • Unlike indifference curves, the labeling of the isoquants represents something measurable, the quantity of output per period. • In addition to the location of the isoquants, economists are also interested in their shape.

  24. Rate of Technical Substitution • The negative of the slope of an isoquant is called the marginal rate of technical substitution (RTS), the amount by which one input can be reduced when one more unit of another input is added while holding output constant. • It is the rate that capital can be reduced, holding output constant, while using one more unit of labor.

  25. Rate of Technical Substitution

  26. Rate of Technical Substitution • The particular value of this trade-off depends upon the level of output and the quantities of capital and labor being used. • At A in Figure 5.2, relatively large amounts of capital can be given up if one more unit of labor is added (large RTS), but at B only a little capital can be sacrificed when adding one more unit of labor (small RTS).

  27. The RTS and Marginal Products • It is likely that the RTS is positive (the isoquant has a negative slope) because the firm can decrease its use of capital if one more unit of labor is employed. • If increasing labor meant the having to hire more capital the marginal product of labor or capital would be negative and the firm would be unwilling to hire more of either.

  28. Diminishing RTS • Along any isoquant the (negative) slope become flatter and the RTS diminishes. • When a relatively large amount of capital is used (as at A in Figure 5.2) a large amount can be replaced by a unit of labor, but when only a small amount of capital is used (as at point B), one more unit of labor replaces very little capital.

  29. APPLICATION 5.3: Engineering and Economics • Engineering studies can be used to provide information about a production function. • Engineers have developed three different methods (A, B, and C) to produce output. • These methods are shown in Figure 1, when method A uses a greater capital labor ratio than B, and the capital labor ratio at B exceeds that at C.

  30. FIGURE 1: Construction of an Isoquant from Engineering Data K per period A B a C c b q0 L per period

  31. APPLICATION 5.3: Engineering and Economics • The points a, b, and c represent three different methods to produce q0 units of output, so these points are one the same isoquant. • This method was used by economists to examine the production of domestic hot water by rooftop solar collectors.

  32. APPLICATION 5.3: Engineering and Economics • This method has been used to examine the extent to which energy and capital can be substituted in industrial equipment design. • Economists have also found that energy and capital are sometimes complements in production, which may have caused the poor productivity of the 1970s due to high energy costs.

  33. Returns to Scale • Returns to scale is the rate at which output increases in response to proportional increases in all inputs. • In the eighteenth century Adam Smith became aware of this concept when he studied the production of pins.

  34. Returns to Scale • Adam Smith identified two forces that come into play when all inputs are increased. • A doubling of inputs permits a greater “division of labor” allowing persons to specialize in the production of specific pin parts. • This specialization may increase efficiency enough to more than double output. • However these benefits might be reversed if firms become too large to manage.

  35. Constant Returns to Scale • A production function is said to exhibit constant returns to scale if a doubling of all inputs results in a precise doubling of output. • This situation is shown in Panel (a) of Figure 5.3.

  36. FIGURE 5.3: Isoquant Maps showing Constant, Decreasing, and Increasing Returns to Scale A Capital per week 4 q = 40 3 q = 30 2 q = 20 1 q = 10 Labor 0 1 2 3 4 per week (a) Constant Returns to Scale

  37. Decreasing Returns to Scale • If doubling all inputs yields less than a doubling of output, the production function is said to exhibit decreasing returns to scale. • This is shown in Panel (b) of Figure 5.3.

  38. FIGURE 5.3: Isoquant Maps showing Constant, Decreasing, and Increasing Returns to Scale A A Capital Capital per week per week 4 4 q = 40 3 q = 30 3 q = 30 2 2 q = 20 q = 20 1 1 q = 10 q = 10 Labor Labor 0 1 2 3 4 0 1 2 3 4 per week per week (a) Constant Returns to Scale (b) Decreasing Returns to Scale

  39. Increasing Returns to Scale • If doubling all inputs results in more than a doubling of output, the production function exhibits increasing returns to scale. • This is demonstrated in Panel (c) of Figure 5.3. • In the real world, more complicated possibilities may exist such as a production function that changes from increasing to constant to decreasing returns to scale.

  40. FIGURE 5.3: Isoquant Maps showing Constant, Decreasing, and Increasing Returns to Scale A A Capital Capital per week per week 4 4 q = 40 3 q = 30 3 q = 30 2 2 q = 20 q = 20 1 1 q = 10 q = 10 Labor Labor 0 1 2 3 4 0 1 2 3 4 per week per week (a) Constant Returns to Scale (b) Decreasing Returns to Scale A Capital per week 4 3 q = 40 2 q = 30 q = 20 1 q = 10 Labor 0 1 2 3 4 per week (c) Increasing Returns to Scale

  41. APPLICATION 5.4: Returns to Scale in Beer Brewing • Because beer is produced in volume (barrels per year) but capital has costs that are proportional to surface area, larger breweries were able to achieve increasing returns to scale. • Economies to scale were also achieved through automated control systems in filling beer cans.

  42. APPLICATION 5.4: Returns to Scale in Beer Brewing • National markets may also foster economies of scale in distribution, advertising (especially television), and marketing. • These factors became especially important after World War II and the number of U.S. brewing firms fell by over 90 percent between 1945 and the mid-1980s.

  43. APPLICATION 5.4: Returns to Scale in Beer Brewing • The output of the industry became consolidated in a few large firms which operated very large breweries in multiple locations to reduce shipping costs. • Beginning the the mid-1980s, however, smaller firms offering premium brands, provided and opening for local microbreweries.

  44. APPLICATION 5.4: Returns to Scale in Beer Brewing • The 1990s have seen a virtual explosion of new brands with odd names or local appeal. • A similar event occurred in great Britain during the 1980s with the “real ale” movements, but it was followed by small firms being absorbed by national brands. • A similar absorption may be starting to take place in the United States.

  45. Input Substitution • Another important characteristic of a production function is how easily inputs can be substituted for each other. • This characteristic depends upon the slope of a given isoquant, rather than the whole isoquant map.

  46. Fixed-Proportions Production Function • It may be the case that absolutely no substitution between inputs is possible. • This case is shown in Figure 5.4. • If K1 units of capital are used, exactly L1 units of labor are required to produce q1 units of output. • If K1 units of capital are used and less than L1 units of labor are used, q1 can not be produced.

  47. Fixed-Proportions Production Function • If K1 units of capital are used and more than L1 units of labor are used, no more than q1 units of output are produced. • With K = K1, the marginal physical product of labor is zero beyond L1 units of labor. • The q1 isoquant is horizontal beyond L1. • Similarly, with L1 units of labor, the marginal physical product of capital is zero beyond K1 resulting in the vertical portion of the isoquant.

  48. FIGURE 5.4: Isoquant Map with Fixed Proportions Capital per week A K2 q2 K1 q1 q0 K0 0 Labor per week L0 L1 L2

  49. Fixed-proportions Production Function • This type of production function is called a fixed-proportion production function because the inputs must be used in a fixed ratio to one another. • Many machines require a fixed complement of workers so this type of production function may be relevant in the real world.

  50. The Relevance of Input Substitutability • Over the past century the U.S. economy has shifted away from agricultural production and towards manufacturing and service industries. • Economists are interested in the degree to which certain factors of production (notable labor) can be moved from agriculture into the growing industries.

More Related