1 / 13

The Department of Justice Versus Alcoa (2000)

The Department of Justice Versus Alcoa (2000). Lance Light Tim Parrington. Background. Alcoa conducts operations in 31 countries and was worth $13 Billion in 1999 and is currently worth approximately $21 Billion

haig
Télécharger la présentation

The Department of Justice Versus Alcoa (2000)

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. The Department of Justice Versus Alcoa (2000) Lance Light Tim Parrington

  2. Background • Alcoa conducts operations in 31 countries and was worth $13 Billion in 1999 and is currently worth approximately $21 Billion • Reynolds Metals Company was the 2nd largest Aluminum producer in the United States and 3rd largest in the world. They were worth $7 Billion in 1999 • Department of Justice issued a complaint in 2000 when Alcoa announced its proposed $5.4 Billion merger with Reynolds (1999)

  3. Relevant Markets • Alcoa and Reynolds primarily produce two types of alumina for the market; SGA (Smelter Grade Alumina) and CGA (Chemical Grade Alumina) • There are no ideal substitutes for either SGA or CGA • Alcoa and Reynolds are both vertically integrated production companies • Only 5 percent of the SGA and CGA purchased in the United States is imported

  4. SSNIP Test • The DOJ will typically employ a SSNIP test to evaluate the effects of a proposed merger by assuming a small (but significant) increase in price • About 60% of the total SGA production is internally consumed by smelters owned by the vertically integrated SGA producers • Importation of CGA and SGA into North America is unlikely to increase significantly in response to an anticompetitive increase in price (of SGA and CGA) because costs are too high

  5. Market Concentration • Alcoa controlled 14.5 million metric tons of SGA production capacity ~29% of the worldwide market (1999) • Reynolds controlled approximately 4.4 million metric tons of total SGA production capacity ~9% of the market. • Alcoa’s market share would increase to nearly 40 percent of total SGA market capacity if the merger is successful

  6. Change in HHI • DOJ evaluated that the HHI for the world SGA market will increase by 530 points • Projected Post-merger HHI of 1,800 • Pre-merger HHI of 1,270 • Increased production share will also increase Alcoa’s North American market share from 39% to 59% (market moves towards oligopoly) • Post-merger: the top three CGA producers will account for almost 90 percent of total production

  7. Anticompetitive Effects • The DOJ’s complaint proposed the following anticompetitive effects: • Future competition between Alcoa and Reynolds will be completely eliminated • Consumer surplus will be partially depleted after the acquisition (lack of production competition) • Prices for SGA and CGA are projected to increase worldwide because of the high market concentration • Overall production quantity of SGA and CGA is likely to decrease

  8. Market Concetration Effects • It is a proposed 5 to 4 merger • Demand for SGA and CGA is extremely inelastic • By reducing its output in the SGA market domestically, Alcoa will have enough projected market share to profit from an increase in price; this is caused by a unilateral reduction in output to third-party SGA and CGA smelters and consumers

  9. Theory of Harm • Violation of the Sherman Act Section 2 • Unilateral Action (Classical) • SGA Market: Control 40% of market, and can use power to dominate the market • CGA Market: Control 60% of the market, significant power to manipulate price • Greater likelihood to Collude • Homogenous product, transparent prices, high concentration of market • Entry & Efficiencies • Entry isn’t possible; Takes 4 years and $1 billion to build a plant capable of competing • Efficiencies argument used by the two firms

  10. Final Judgment • Merger allowed, following divestitures • US requirements: • Corpus Christi refinery (owned 100%) • With contract for providing raw product for 2 years • Worsley Interest (owned 56%) • EU Requirements: • Longview, Washington smelter (owned 25%) • Stade, Germany refinery (owned 50%)

  11. Our Opinion • Corpus Christi divestiture (not enough) • too high of costs, bought by private investment firm • Worsley interest divestiture (good choice) • Low cost with ability to expand • But it was sold to another large firm • Could still promote collusion • Didn’t evaluate vertical repercussions at all • Overall, we believe it should have been given a more thorough review

  12. Conclusion • It set a dangerous precedent; Alcoa merged again, more aluminum mergers allowed • Prices increased (but this correlates with a high demand for aluminum) Average aluminum distribution prices (1999-2011)

  13. Sources • AAI Attacks Proposed Acquisition of Reynolds. (2000). Retrieved April 15, 2011, from American Antitrust Institute Web site: http://www.antitrustinstitute.org/node/10161 • http://www.alcoa.com/global/en/news/news_releases.asp?year=2000&catID=&catName=Select+a+Category • Aluminum Industry. (n.d.). Retrieved April 15, 2011, from Aluminum Leader: http://www.aluminiumleader.com/en/serious/industry/ • Aluminum Prices. (2011). Retrieved April 16, 2011, from Mongabay Web site: http://www.mongabay.com/images/commodities/charts/aluminum.html • Communities, C. o. (May 3, 2000). Case No COMP/M.1693 - Alcoa/Reynolds. Official Journal of the European Communities , Article 8 (2). • Curran, W. J. (2004). Coordinated Effects. The Antitrust Bulletin , 226-310. • Justice, D. o. (2002). Coordinated Effects in Merger Review. Antitrust Division Reports , 1-23. • United States v. Alcoa and Reynolds Metals. (2000). Retrieved March 28, 2011, from Department of Justice: Antitrust Case Filings: http://www.justice.gov/atr/cases/indx157a. • (1) Yeardley, James L. "The Alcoa Proposition." InterestPeople 4th ser. 13.3 (2000): 21-23. Chinook. Web. 20 Apr. 2011 • (2) Horacio, M. Glimpchin, T. “Merger Busts?” The Transit • 2nd ser. 3.6 (2003): 50-51. Chinook. Web. 20 Apr. 2011. • (3) Wayne, Leslie. "Alcoa and Reynolds Reach Merger Agreement - New York Times." Breaking News, World News & Multimedia. New York Times, 20 Aug. 1999. Web. 22 Apr. 2011. http://www.nytimes.com/1999/08/20/business/alcoa-and-reynolds-reach-merger-agreement.html. • (4) Alcoa Logo retrieved from: http://www.google.com/imgres?imgurl=http://www.goodlogo.com/images/logos/alcoa_logo_2881.gif&imgrefurl=http://www.goodlogo.com/extended.info/2881& • (5) Reynolds Metals Company logo retrieved from: • http://www.google.com/imgres?imgurl=http://upload.wikimedia.org/wikipedia/en/thumb/7/76/Reynolds_Metals_Company.svg/500px-Reynolds_Metals_Company.svg.png&imgrefurl=http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/File:Reynolds_Metals_Company.svg&usg=__M-tPz7sDLm3Duk2lq

More Related