260 likes | 398 Vues
9. Binary Dependent Variables. 9.1 Homogeneous models Logit, probit models Inference Tax preparers 9.2 Random effects models 9.3 Fixed effects models 9.4 Marginal models and GEE Appendix 9A - Likelihood calculations. 9.1 Homogeneous models.
E N D
9. Binary Dependent Variables • 9.1 Homogeneous models • Logit, probit models • Inference • Tax preparers • 9.2 Random effects models • 9.3 Fixed effects models • 9.4 Marginal models and GEE • Appendix 9A - Likelihood calculations
9.1 Homogeneous models • The response of interest, yit, now may be only a 0 or a 1, a binary dependent variable. • Typically indicates whether the ith subject possesses an attribute at time t. • Suppose that the probability that the response equals 1 is denoted by Prob(yit = 1) = pit. • Then, we may interpret the mean response to be the probability that the response equals 1 , that is, E yit= 0 Prob(yit = 0) + 1 Prob(yit = 1) = pit . • Further, straightforward calculations show that the variance is related to the mean through the expression Var yit= pit (1 - pit) .
Inadequacy of linear models • Homogeneous means that we will not incorporate subject-specific terms that account for heterogeneity. • Linear models of the form yit = xit + it are inadequate because: • The expected response is a probability and thus must vary between 0 and 1 although the linear combination, xit, may vary between negative and positive infinity. • Linear models assume homoscedasticity (constant variance) yet the variance of the response depends on the mean which varies over observations. • The response must be either a 0 or 1 although the distribution of the error term is typically regarded as continuous.
Using nonlinear functions of explanatory variables • In lieu of linear, or additive, functions, we express the probability of the response being 1 as a nonlinear function of explanatory variables pit = (xit). • Two special cases are: • the logit case • (z ) as a cumulative standard normal distribution function, the probit case. • These two functions are similar. I focus on the logit case because it permits closed-form expressions unlike the cumulative normal distribution function.
Threshold interpretation • Suppose that there exists an underlying linear model, yit* = xit + it*. • The response is interpreted to be the “propensity” to possess a characteristic. • We do not observe the propensity but we do observe when the propensity crosses a threshold, say 0. • We observe • Using the logit distribution function, Prob (it*a) = 1/ (1 + exp(-a) ) • Note that Prob(-it*xit) = Prob(it*xit). Thus,
Random utility interpretation • In economics applications, we think of an individual choosing among c categories. • Preferences among categories are indexed by an unobserved utility function. • We model utility as a function of an underlying value plus random noise, that is, Uitj = uit(Vitj + eitj), j = 0,1. • If Uit1 > Uit0 , then denote this choice as yit = 1. • Assuming that uit is a strictly increasing function, we have • Parameterize the problem by taking Vit0 = 0 and Vit1 = xit β. • We may take the difference in the errors, it0 - it1 , to be normal or logistic, corresponding to the probit and logit cases.
Logistic regression • This is another phrase used to describe the logit case. • Using p = (z), the inverse of can be calculated as z = -1(p) = ln ( p/(1-p) ) . • Define logit (p) = ln ( p/(1-p) ) to be the logit function. • Here, p/(1-p) is known as the odds ratio. It has a convenient economic interpretation in terms of fair games. • That is, suppose that p = 0.25. Then, the odds ratio is 0.333. • The odds against winning are 0.333 to 1, or 1 to 3. If we bet $1, then in a fair game we should win $3. • The logistic regression models the linear combination of explanatory variables as the logarithm of the odds ratio, xit = ln ( pit/(1-pit) ) .
Parameter interpretation • To interpret =( 1, 2, …, K), we begin by assuming that jth explanatory variable, xitj, is either 0 or 1. • Then, with the notation, we may interpret • Thus, • To illustrate, if j = 0.693, then exp(j) = 2. • The odds (for y = 1) are twice as great for xj = 1 as for xj = 0.
More parameter interpretation • Similarly, assuming that jth explanatory variable is continuous, we have • Thus, we may interpret j as the proportional change in the odds ratio, known as an elasticity in economics.
Parameter estimation • The customary estimation method is maximum likelihood. • The log likelihood of a single observation is • The log likelihood of the data set is • Taking partial derivatives with respect to b yields the score equations • The solution of these equations, say bMLE, yields the maximum likelihood estimate. • The score equations can also be expressed as a generalized estimating equation: • where
For the logit function • The normal equations are: • The solution depends on the responses yit only through the vector of statistics itxityit . • The solution of these equations, say bMLE, yields the maximum likelihood estimate bMLE . • This method can be extended to provide standard errors for the estimates.
9.2 Random effects models • We accommodate heterogeneity by incorporating subject-specific variables of the form: pit = (i + xit ). • We assume that the intercepts are realizations of random variables from a common distribution. • We estimate the parameters of the {i} distribution and the K slope parameters . • By using the random effects specification, we dramatically reduced the number of parameters to be estimated compared to the Section 9.3 fixed effects set-up. • This is similar to the linear model case. • This model is computationally difficult to evaluate.
Commonly used distributions • We assume that subject-specific effects are independent and come from a common distribution. • It is customary to assume that the subject-specific effects are normally distributed. • We assume, conditional on subject-specific effects, that the responses are independent. Thus, there is no serial correlation. • There are two commonly used specifications of the conditional distributions in the random effects panel data model. • 1. A logistic model for the conditional distribution of a response. That is, • 2. A normal model for the conditional distribution of a response. That is, • where is the standard normal distribution function.
Likelihood • Let Prob(yit = 1| i) =(i + xit) denote the conditional probability for both the logistic and normal models. • Conditional on i, the likelihood for the it thobservation is: • Conditional on i, the likelihood for the ith subject is: • Thus, the (unconditional) likelihood for the ith subject is: • Here, is the standard normal density function. • Hence, the total log-likelihood is i ln li . • Note: lots of evaluations of a numerical integral….
Comparing logit to probit specification • There are no important advantages or disadvantages when choosing the conditional probability to be: • logit function (logit model) • standard normal (probit model) • The likelihood involves roughly the same amount of work to evaluate and maximize, although the logit function is slightly easier to evaluate than the standard normal distribution function. • The probit model is slightly easier to interpret because unconditional probabilities can be expressed in terms of the standard normal distribution function. • That is,
9.3 Fixed effects models • As with homogeneous models, we express the probability of the response being 1 as a nonlinear function of linear combinations of explanatory variables. • To accommodate heterogeneity, we incorporate subject-specific variables of the form: pit = (i + xit). • Here, the subject-specific effects account only for the intercepts and do not include other variables. • We assume that {i} are fixed effects in this section. • In this chapter, we assume that responses are serially uncorrelated. • Important point: Panel data with dummy variables provide inconsistent parameter estimates….
Maximum likelihood estimation • Unlike random effect models, maximum likelihood estimators are inconsistent in fixed effects models. • The log likelihood of the data set is • This log likelihood can still be maximized to yield maximum likelihood estimators. • However, as the subject size n tends to infinity, the number of parameters also tends to infinity. • Intuitively, our ability to estimate is corrupted by our inability to estimate consistently the subject-specific effects {i} . • In the linear case, we had that the maximum likelihood estimates are equivalent to the least squares estimates. • The least squares estimates of were consistent. • The least squares procedure “swept out” intercept estimators when producing estimates of .
Maximum likelihood estimation is inconsistent • Example 9.2 (Chamberlain, 1978, Hsiao 1986). • Let Ti = 2, K=1 and xi1 = 0 and xi2=1. • Take derivatives of the likelihood function to get the score functions – these are in display (9.8). • From (9.8), the score functions are • and • Appendix 9A.1 • Maximize this to get bmle • Show that the probability limit of bmle is 2 , and hence is an inconsistent estimator of .
Conditional maximum likelihood estimation • This estimation technique provides consistent estimates of the beta coefficients. • It is due to Chamberlain (1980) in the context of fixed effects panel data models. • Let’s consider the logit specification of , so that • Big idea: With this specification, it turns out that tyitis a sufficient statistic for i. • Thus, if we condition on tyit, then the distribution of the responses will not depend on i.
Example of the sufficiency • To illustrate how to separate the intercept from the slope effects, consider the case Ti = 2. • Suppose that the sum, tyit = yi1+yi2, equals either 0 or 2. • If sum equals 0, then Prob (yi1 = 0, yi2 = 0 |yi1 + yi2 = sum) = 1. • If sum equals 2, then Prob (yi1 = 1, yi2 = 1 |yi1 + yi2 = sum) = 1. • Both conditional probabilities do not depend on i . • Both conditional events are certain and will contribute nothing to a conditional likelihood. • If sum equals 1,
Example of the sufficiency • Thus, • This does not depend on i. • Note that if an explanatory variable xij is time-constant (xij2 xij1 ), then the corresponding parameter j disappears from the conditional likelihood.
Conditional likelihood estimation • Let Sibe the random variable representing tyit and let sumi be the realization of t yit . • The conditional likelihood of the data set is • Note that the ratio equals one when sumi equal 0 or Ti. • The distribution of Si is messy and is difficult to compute for moderate size data sets with T more than 10. • This provides a fix for the problem of “infinitely many nuisance parameters.” • Computationally difficult, hard to extend to more complex models, hard to explain to consumers
9.4 Marginal models and GEE • Marginal models, also know as “population-averaged” models, only require specification of the first two moments • Means, variances and covariances • Not a true probability model • Ideal for moment estimation (GEE, GMM) • Begin in the context of the random effects binary dependent variable model • The mean is E yit = • The variance is Var yit = mit (1- mit ). • The covariance is Cov (yir, yis)
GEE – generalized estimating equations • This is a method of moments procedure • Essentially the same as generalized method of moments • One matches theoretical moments to sample moments, with appropriate weighting. • Idea – find the values of the parameters that satisfy • We have already specified the variance matrix. • We also use a K x Ti matrix of derivatives • For binary variables, we have
Marginal Model • Choose the mean function to be • Motivated by probit specification • For the variance function, consider Var yit = it (1- it). • Let Corr(yir, yis) denote the correlation between yir and yis. • This is known as a working correlation. • Use the exchangeable correlation structure specified as • Here, the motivation is that the latent variable i is common to all observations within a subject, thus inducing a common correlation. • The parameters τ = (, ) constitute the variance components.
Robust Standard Errors • Model-based standard errors are taken from the square root of the diagonal elements of • As an alternative, robust or empirical standards errors are from • These are robust to misspecified heterscedasticity as well as time series correlation.